Skip to main content
PLOS One logoLink to PLOS One
. 2021 Jul 19;16(7):e0253956. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0253956

Interest on reserves, helicopter money and new monetary policy

Duong Ngotran 1,*
Editor: Mikael Bask2
PMCID: PMC8289106  PMID: 34280205

Abstract

We build a nonlinear dynamic model with currency, demand deposits and bank reserves. Monetary base is controlled by central bank, while money supply is determined by the interactions between central bank, commercial banks and public. In economic crises when banks cut loans, monetary policy following a Taylor rule is not efficient. Negative interest on reserves or forward guidance is effective, but deflation is still likely to be persistent. If central bank simultaneously targets both interest rate and money supply by a Taylor rule and a Friedman’s k-percent rule, inflation and output are stabilized. An interest rate rule policy is just a subset of a more general monetary policy framework in which central bank can move interest rate and money supply in every direction.

Introduction

In the Great Recession and the recent COVID-19 crisis, the federal funds rate and the ECB policy rate have been near zero or even negative for a long time. Still, the deflation pressures have been so high in US and Europe. This phenomenon raised many concerns among economists and policy makers on how central bank’s policy should be designed. Some possible solutions for raising inflation in this circumstance are forward guidance, helicopter money and quantitative easing [1, 2]. The last two tools can directly change money supply; however they cannot be a daily tool like an interest rate targeting policy in the standard monetary policy framework. This paper shows that central bank can add a Friedman’s k-percent rule (money supply targeting) into the current standard framework (interest rate targeting) to hit the inflation target in economic crises.

The common traditional consensus among economists is that central bank cannot target both interest rate and money supply at the same time. Central bank chooses either monetary base as its main instrument [35] or the common interbank rate [6]. Nevertheless, the introduction of a new monetary policy tool—interest on reserves (IOR)—and the transformation of economy from making transactions with currency to electronic money will allow central bank to use both instruments. With IOR, the price of reserves might disconnect from the quantity of reserves in the banking system. With electronic money, money can earn a positive nominal interest rate. Therefore, it is a possible scenario that central bank can increase the level of reserves and raise rates at the same time.

This paper builds a dynamic model with bank reserves, currency, and demand deposits. The monetary base in our model is controlled by central bank, while the money supply is determined by the interactions between central bank, banks and public. The interbank rate is controlled either by open market operations or by adjusting IOR, so a wide range of conventional and unconventional monetary policies can be assessed in this model.

The main contribution of this paper is to characterize a new model of monetary policy when central bank can “simultaneously” and “actively” move money supply and interest rate in every direction. In textbooks, when money supply increases, interest rate goes down. However, in the electronic monetary system, if central bank wants, interest rate can go up when money supply increases. An interest rate rule policy (without manipulating money supply) is just a subset of a more general monetary policy framework.

By using this model, we still find that in normal times, an interest rate policy following a Taylor rule is an effective mean of controlling an economy. When central bank cuts rates, the amount of money supply increases because banks create more loans. As price is sticky in our model, outputs are stimulated in the short run due to the rise in the aggregate demand. The effect is identical to a standard New Keynesian model.

However, in economic crises when banks cannot make loans due to the capital constraints, a policy following a Taylor rule is insufficient for lowering real loan rates in our model. Even with a negative IOR or forward guidance, the outcome is only slightly better. The main reason is that the inflationary expectations also depend on the path of the money supply. Because of the decline in the endogenous money supply, our model shows that the deflation expectation happens in these economic crises. As a result of that, the real loan rate will be high even though the interbank rate touches the zero lower bound.

Targeting both money supply (by using helicopter money) and interest rate (by adjusting IOR) is very efficient in our model simulation. We find that central bank only needs to follow a simple Taylor rule and a Friedman’s k-percent rule so that both outputs and inflation will be stabilized. After the crisis time, central bank can always come back to a simple Taylor rule alone.

Related literature

Our model shares many similarities with a standard New Keynesian framework with the existence of a banking sector [711]. Banks play a role of intermediaries channeling funds from savers to borrowers in these models; while our model focuses on the function of creating money in the banking sector [12]. Banking crises create a liquidity problem for agents in the private sector as money supply declines. In this sense, our model is identical to [13], where a shock worsening the liquidity of pseudo-safe assets can create a crisis with a persistent deflation.

Our model also relates to a New Keynesian framework with money demand in the form of cash/deposit in advance [1416]. Money (for households) could be either cash or deposits. Households need them in advance before making any transactions in the good and capital markets.

The salient feature separating our model from a standard New Keynesian is the money supply process and electronic payment system. Central bank in our model controls monetary base, but money supply is determined by the interactions between central bank, banks and public. [17, 18] characterize how central banks control reserves and manipulate the interbank rate, but the money supply part has not been explored in these papers.

To target both money supply and interest rate, central bank has to use IOR. This tool is already mentioned in the literature [1924]. Our model, different from this line of research, can connect IOR with banking reserves, money supply and interbank rate in a micro-founded dynamic setup.

We also discuss two unconventional monetary policies: negative IOR and forward guidance. The analysis of monetary policy with a negative interest rate can be found in [25]. Our model emphasizes the transmission through a negative IOR to the interbank rate and the deposit rate while the framework in [25] directly assumes that central bank can impose a negative short term rate. In both papers, the negative rate might be an important tool when the interbank rate is near zero. We also examine the effect of central bank’s forward guidance policy [2630] in a banking crisis context.

This paper extends the model in [31] to a more general environment, including both currency and electronic money. The model is very similar to a standard New Keynesian model, except the flows of electronic payments and the banker problem. Banking crises are the main themes in both papers and the effectiveness of different hypothetical polices are assessed under this context. However, [31] studies the inflation dynamics after the Great Recession and the appropriate policy to get out of the low interest rate environment. This paper focuses on a new type of monetary policy when central bank targets both money supply and interest rate by two common monetary policy rules.

The environment

Notation

Let Pt be the price of the final good. We use lowercase letters to represent the real balance of a variable or its relative price. For example, the real reserves balance nt = Nt/Pt, or the real price of intermediate goods ptm=Ptm/Pt. The timing notation follows this rule: if a variable is determined or chosen at time t, it will have the subscript t. The gross inflation rate is πt = Pt/Pt−1.

Goods and production technology

We closely follow the model description in [31]. Our model extends [31] to an environment where currency and demand deposits coexist.

The model is in the deterministic setting and has six types of agents: bankers, households, wholesale firms, two types of retail firms (c-retailers and d-retailers), and a consolidated government.

There are four types of goods in the economy: cash-goods y1,t produced by c-retailers who only accept currency as the mean of payment, deposit-goods y2,t produced by d-retailers who only accept payment through banks, wholesale goods yt(j) produced by wholesale firm j and intermediate good ytm produced by households.

Each period households self-employ their labor lt to produce the homogeneous intermediate good ytm under the production function:

ytm=lt

Households sell ytm to wholesale firms in the competitive market with the price Ptm.

There is a continuum of wholesale firms indexed by j ∈ [0, 1]. Each wholesale firm purchases the homogeneous intermediate good ytm from households and differentiates it into a distinctive wholesale goods yt(j) under the following technology:

yt(j)=ytm

Wholesale firms faces the Rotemberg adjustment cost when they change their prices.

Two types of retail firms both produce the final good yi,t (i = 1, 2) by aggregating a variety of differentiated wholesale goods yt(j):

yi,t=(01yt(j)ϵ-1ϵdj)ϵϵ-1,i=1,2

As the markets for cash-goods and deposit-goods are perfectly competitive and they have the same constant return to scale production function, they have the same price Pt.

Time, demographics and preferences

Time is discrete, indexed by t and continues forever.

There is a measure one of identical infinitely lived bankers in the economy. Bankers discount the future with the discount factor β. Each period, they gain utility from consuming a basket ct that contains cash-goods c1,t and deposit-goods c2,t. Their utility at the period t can be written as:

s=0βslog(ct+s),withct=[i=12αi1σci,tσ-1σ]σσ-1

where αi is the share of cash-goods or deposit-goods in the basket and σ is the elasticity of substitution between two goods in the basket.

There is also a measure one of identical infinitely lived households. Households discount the future with the discount factor β˜<β, so they will borrow from bankers in the steady state. This setup is similar to a model with two types of agents: patient and impatient households. Banks are owned by patient households, so impatient households borrow from banks. Banks will transfer profits to patient households.

Similar to bankers, each period households gain utility from consuming the basket c˜t and lose utility when providing labor lt to their own production. Household’s utility at the period t can be written as:

s=0β˜s[log(c˜t+s)-χlt+s],withc˜t=[i=12αi1σc˜i,tσ-1σ]σσ-1

where χ is the weight of labor in the utility function.

Wholesale firms and retail firms are owned by households. The consolidated government includes both the government and the central bank, so for convenience, we assume there is no independence between the government and the central bank.

Assets

There are two types of financial assets: bank loans to households Bth and interbank loans Btf.

  • Bank loans to households (Bth): We follow [14] to model the loan structure between bankers and households. The market for bank loan is perfectly competitive and the price of loan is qtl. When a household wants to borrow 1 dollar at time t, bankers will create an account for her and deposit qtl dollars to her account. In the exchange for that, this household promises to pay δb, δb(1 − δb), …, δb(1 − δb)n−1, δb(1 − δb)n… dollars at time t + 1, t + 2, … t + n, t + n + 1… where n runs to infinity and 0 < δb ≤ 1 (Table 1). Loans are illiquid and bankers cannot sell loans.

    Let Bth be the nominal balance of loan stock in the period t, let St be the nominal flow of new loan issuance, we have:
    Bth=(1-δb)Bt-1h+St
  • Interbank loan (Btf): Bankers can borrow reserves from other bankers in the interbank market. The nominal gross interest rate in the interbank market is the interbank rate Rtf.

Table 1. Banker issues loans (left) and collects on loans (right).

Banker Banker
Loans: +St Deposits: +qtlSt Loans: -δbBt-1h Deposits: -δbBt-1h
Net worth: +(1-qtl)St

Money and payment system

There are three types of money in our economy: currency xt, zero-maturity deposits mt and reserves nt.

  • Currency (xt): is issued by central bank and held by households. If currency is held by bankers, it is automatically converted to reserves. Currency is used for transactions between households/bankers and c-retailers who sell cash-goods. Currency does not pay nominal interest. The amount of currency in circulation is endogenous in the equilibrium.

  • Zero maturity deposit (ZMD) (mt): is a type of e-money (IOU) issued by bankers. ZMDs have the same unit of account as currency. When holding these deposits, households earn a gross nominal interest rate Rtm which is determined by the perfectly competitive banking market. ZMDs are used for settling all transactions in the private sector, except for transactions between households/bankers and c-retailers. When the market between bankers and households open, household can convert ZMDs to currency or currency to ZMDs. They are insured by central bank, so they are totally safe.

  • Reserve (nt): is a type of e-money (IOU) issued by central bank for only bankers. It has the same unit of account with currency. Central bank pays a gross interest rate Rtn for these reserves. Interest on reserves Rtn is a monetary policy tool of central bank. At any moments, bankers can convert these reserves to currency and pay households. Reserves are used for settling transactions between bankers and bankers, bankers and the consolidated government.

Transactions with currency are simple. However, transactions with zero maturity deposits relates to many parties. We repeat the example in [31] to illustrate the connection between the flows of ZMDs and reserves. If wholesale firm A (whose account at bank A) pays 1 dollars to household B (whose account at bank B), the flows of payment will follow Table 2.

Table 2. Electronic payment system.

Wholesale firm A Household B
Deposit: -1 Payable:-1 Deposit: +1
Receivable:-1
Bank A Bank B
Reserve: -1 Deposit: -1 Reserve: +1 Deposit: +1
The Central Bank
Reserve (bank A): -1
Reserve (bank B): +1

Central bank and monetary policy

Central bank always uses the electronic payment system to conduct monetary policy. Each period, central bank transfers τt dollars to households’ account. This can be seen as a shortcut of an open market operation process when central bank purchases government bonds from government. Then government transfers the payoffs to households. When τt is negative, it is equivalent to a lump-sum tax. For any transactions between central bank and households, as the payments are conducted through the banking system, we should think that they contain two sub-transactions: one between central bank-bankers is settled by reserves, one between bankers—households is settled by ZMDs (Table 3).

Table 3. Helicopter money / lump-sum tax.

The Central Bank Banks Public
Reserves: +τt Reserves: +τt Deposits: +τt Deposits: +τt Net worth: +τt
Net worth: -τt

Timing within one period

  1. Production takes place. Households sell goods to wholesalers, who, in turn, sell goods to retailers. All of the payments between households-wholesalers, wholesalers-retailers are delayed until the step 5

  2. The cash-good market opens. Households need cash-in-advance to purchase from c-retailers. Bankers can convert reserves to cash to purchase from c-retailers.

  3. The loan market between households and bankers opens. All the debt payments and loan issuance will be conducted electronically. The government transfers money to households. Households cannot exchange cash and deposits in this step.

  4. The deposit-good market opens. Households need ZMD-in-advance to purchase goods from d-retailers. Bankers can create ZMDs to purchase d-goods.

  5. Payments in the non-bank private sector are settled. Profits from firms are transfered back to households under either form of cash or ZMDs. Households can go to banks and readjust their portfolio between cash and deposits.

  6. The banking market opens. Bankers can adjust the level of reserves by borrowing in the interbank market, receiving new deposits.

Agents’ problems

Bankers

There is a measure one of identical bankers in the economy. These bankers have to follow central bank’s regulations. There are three types of assets on a banker’s balance sheet: reserves (nt), loans to households (bth), loans to other bankers (btf). His liability side contains the zero-maturity deposits that households deposit here (mt).

graphic file with name pone.0253956.e214.jpg

Cost

The banker faces a cost of managing loan, which is θbth in terms of deposit-goods.

The banker can adjust the level of his deposits and reserves after households and firms pay each other or when households withdraw currency from bank account. When these happen, the banker can witness that the deposits and reserves outflow from or inflow to his bank. Let et be the net inflow of deposits and reserves going into his bank, he will treat et as exogenous. When the banking market opens, as the deposit market is perfectly competitive, he can choose any amounts dt of deposit inflows or outflows to his bank.

In each period, the banker treats all the prices as exogenous and chooses {ct, c1,t, c2,t, nt, bth,st,mt,btf,dt} to maximize his utility over a stream of consumption:

maxt=0βtlog(ct)

subject to

Rt-1nnt-1πt+Rt-1fbt-1fπt+dt+et+τt=nt+btf+c1,t(ReserveFlows) (1)
mt=Rt-1mmt-1πt+qtlst+θbth-δbbt-1hπt+c2,t+dt+et+τt(DepositFlows) (2)
bth=(1-δb)bt-1hπt+st(LoanFlows) (3)
ct=[i=12αi1σci,tσ-1σ]σσ-1(Consumption) (4)
ntφmt(ReserveRequirement) (5)
nt+btf+bth-mtκtbth(CapitalRequirement) (6)

Eq (1) shows the change in reserves in the banker’s balance sheet. After receiving the IOR, the previous balance of reserves becomes Rt-1nnt-1/πt. He also collects payments from the interbank loans that he lends out to other bankers in the previous period Rt-1fbt-1f/πt. He can also increase his reserves by taking more deposits dt. When doing that, his reserves and his liability increase by the same amount dt (Table 4). That is the reason we see dt appear on both the Eqs (1) and (2). The similar effect can be found on τt- helicopter money and et. The banker treats τt and et exogenously. Then, he can leave reserves nt at central bank’s account to earn interest rate, or lend reserves to another bankers btf. To purchase cash-goods c1,t from c-retailers, he converts reserves into currency (Table 5).During one period, his reserves balance can be temporarily negative. Still, in the end of every period, it must be positive and satisfies the regulation. Hence, the constraint in purchasing cash-goods implicitly lies in the reserve requirement.

Table 4. Banker takes deposits (left) and makes interbank loan (right).
Banker Banker
Reserves: +dt Deposits: +dt Reserves: -btf
Interbank loan: +btf
Table 5. Banker buys goods from c-retailers.
Central Bank Banker c-Retailers
Reserves: -c1,t Reserves: -c1,t Net worth: Currency: +c1,t
Currency: +c1,t (Vault Cash) -c1,t Inventory: -c1,t

Eq (2) shows the change in the banker’s deposits. He makes loans to households by issuing deposits or creating ZMDs (Table 1). It is assumed that households have to pay loans from the account at the bank they borrow. The banker also issues his own ZMDs to purchase the consumption good from d-retailers (c2,t) and to pay for the cost (in terms of deposit-goods) related to lending activities (θbth) (Table 6). It is noted that he cannot create infinite amount of money for himself to buy consumption goods as there exists the capital requirement. Even without the capital requirement, because deposits are bankers’ debts, the No-Ponzi condition is enough to prevent that action.

Table 6. Banker buys goods from d-retailers.
Banker d-Retailers
Deposits: +(c2,t+θbth) Deposits: +(c2,t+θbth)
Net worth: -(c2,t+θbth) Inventory: -(c2,t+θbth)

The banker faces two constraints in every period. At the end of each period, he has to hold enough reserves as a fraction of total deposits, which is showed in the Eq (5).

The second constraint is the capital requirement constraint. The left hand side of (6) is the banker’s net worth (capital), which is equal to total assets minus total liabilities. We use the book value Bth rather than the “market value” of loans qtlBth in the capital constraint. The reason is that illiquid bank loans should be treated differently from bonds. In reality, bank loans are often not revalued in the balance sheet when the interest rate changes. The constraint requires the banker to hold capital greater than a fraction of total loans in his balance sheet. We assume that κt is a constant κ in normal times. We later put the unexpected shock on this κt to reflect the shock in a banking crisis.

Let γt, μtr and μtc be respectively the Lagrangian multipliers associated to the reserves flows, reserves constraint and the capital constraint. Let rth be defined as the real short-term lending rate. The first order conditions of the banker’s problem can be written as:

γt=(αictci,t)1/σ1ct,i=1,2 (7)
γt=βRtfγt+1πt+1+μtc (8)
γt=βRtmγt+1πt+1+μtc+φμtr (9)
γt=βRtnγt+1πt+1+μtc+μtr (10)
(qtl+θ)γt=β[δb+(1-δb)qt+1l]γt+1πt+1+(1-κ)μtc (11)
rth=δb+(1-δb)qt+1l(qtl+θ)πt+1 (12)

And two complimentary slackness conditions:

μtr0,nt-φmt0,μtr(nt-φmt)=0 (13)
μtc0,nt+btf+(1-κt)bth-mt0,μtc(nt+btf+(1-κt)bth-mt)=0 (14)

Households

There is a measure one of identical households. These self-employed households produce homogeneous intermediate good ytm to sell to the wholesale firms at price Ptm. In each period, a household consumes cash-goods (c˜1,t) from c-retailers and deposit-goods (c˜2,t) from d-retailers.

Let B˜th be the nominal debt stock that she borrows from bankers. The loan structure follows the description in Table 1. There is an exogenous borrowing constraint for households with the debt limit b˜thbh¯.

In each period, households choose {c˜t,lt,at,xt,b˜th,m˜t,s˜t,c˜1,t,c˜2,t} to maximize their expected utility:

maxt=0β˜t(log(c˜t)-χlt)

subject to

CIA:c˜1,txt-1πt (15)
LoanMarket:at+δbb˜t-1hπt=Rt-1mmt-1πt+qtlst+τt (16)
DIA:c˜2,tat (17)
Budget:m˜t+xt+c˜1,t+c˜2,t=at+xt-1πt+ptmytm+ΠtPt (18)
Production:ytm=lt (19)
Loanflows:b˜th=(1-δb)b˜t-1hπt+s˜t (20)
Constraint:b˜thbh¯ (21)
Consumption:c˜t=[i=12αi1σc˜i,tσ-1σ]σσ-1 (22)

When the cash-good market opens, the household brings (xt−1/πt) in cash to make transactions there. She faces the cash-in-advance constraint (15) when purchasing goods from c-retailers.

The loan market between bankers and households (Eq 16) only opens after that. Here the household pays a fraction of her old debts (δbbt-1h/πt) and borrows new loan (qtlst). All of the transactions are conducted electronically. We have assumed that she cannot readjust her portfolio between cash and deposits in this step. In the end, she brings at amount of ZMDs to purchase goods from d-retailers.

Eq (18) is the household’s general budget constraint. After receiving the profits (Πt/Pt) from wholesalers and revenue (ptmytm) from selling the intermediate good, she can go to banks and readjust her portfolio between deposits (mt) and currency (xt).

Let η1,t, η2,t, ηtb be the Lagrangian for the cash-in-advance, the deposit-in-advance and the borrowing constraint. Let λt be the Lagrangian for the budget constraint.

λt+ηi,t=(αic˜tc˜i,t)1/σ1c˜t,i=1,2 (23)
ptmλt=χ (24)
λt=β˜(λt+1+η1,t+1)πt+1 (25)
λt=β˜Rtm(λt+1+η2,t+1)πt+1 (26)
qtl(λt+η2,t)=β˜[δb+(1-δb)qt+1l](λt+1+η2,t+1)πt+1+ηtb (27)

And three complimentary slackness conditions:

η1,t0,xt-1πt-c˜1,t0,η1,t(xt-1πt-c˜1,t)=0 (28)
η2,t0,at-c˜2,t0,η2,t(at-c˜2,t)=0 (29)
ηtb0,bh¯-bth0,ηtb(bh¯-bth)=0 (30)

Retail firms and wholesale firms

Following Rotemberg pricing, each wholesale firm j faces a cost of adjusting prices, which is measured in terms of final good and given by:

ι2(Pt(j)Pt-1(j)-π¯)2yt

where ι determines the degree of nominal price rigidity and π¯ is the long-run inflation target. The wholesale firm j discounts the profit in the future with rate β˜iλt+i/λt. Her real marginal cost is ptm.

In a symmetric equilibrium, all firms will choose the same price and produce the same quantity Pt(j) = Pt and yt(j)=yt=ytm. The optimal pricing rule then implies that:

1-ι(πt-π¯)πt+ιβ˜[λt+1λt(πt+1-π¯)πt+1yt+1yt]=(1-ptm)ϵ (31)

The central bank and government

The consolidated government uses the payoffs from tax to pay for the IOR, then injects (withdraws) τ^t amount of money to (from) households to target the interbank rate. All transactions are conducted through the banking system.

τt=-(Rt-1n-1)nt-1πt+τ^t (32)

In the conventional monetary policy, we assume that the IOR Rtn is fixed at a constant level Rn¯. The interbank rate follows a common Taylor rule. To connect with the common New Keynesian literature, we assume that central bank does not want to have excess reserves in the banking system so they never set Rtf lower than Rn¯+δf where δf > 0. When the reserve requirement is no longer binding, there are infinite levels of reserves that can satisfy the interbank rate at its lower bound. In this case, we need a rule governing the motion of reserves and change the standard Taylor Rule. Later, we will relax the assumption and examine the situation when the banking system is awash of excess reserves and central bank controls the interbank rate by adjusting Rtn.

The conventional monetary policy rule can be described as:

Rtn=Rn¯ (33)
Rtf=max{π¯β(πt+1π¯)ϕπ,Rn¯+δf} (34)

Equilibrium

Definition: A perfect foresight equilibrium is a sequence of bankers’ decision choice {ct, ci,t, nt, bth, st, mt, btf, dt}, household’s choice {c˜t,c˜i,t,b˜th,s˜t,m˜t,xt,lt,ytm}, the firms’ choice {yt}, central bank’ choice {τt, Rtn}, and the market price {qtl,Rtf,πt,ptm} such that:

  1. Given the market price, the initial conditions and central bank’s choices, banker’s choices solve the banker’s problem, household’s choices solve the household’s problem, firm’s choice solves the firm’s problem.

  2. All markets clear:
    Netinflowsofdeposits:dt+et=-(xt-xt-1πt-c1,t) (35)
    Theinterbankmarket:btf=0 (36)
    TotalZMDs:mt=m˜t
    LoanMarket:bth=b˜th
    GoodMarket:yt=i=12(ci,t+c˜i,t)+θbth+ι2(πt-π¯)2yt (37)

Later, we set some different central bank’s monetary polices subject to a set of equations in this perfect foresight equilibrium. In each case, we might also change the set of central bank’s monetary policy tools. For convenience, we define (AD) as the set of equations in the perfect foresight equilibrium, excluding the monetary policy and exogenous shocks.

Definition: Let (AD) contain the set of equations and conditions in (44)(66) (Mathematical Appendix).

Theoretical results

We make the following assumption to ensure that households borrow from bankers in the steady state.

Assumption 1. The discount factors of bankers and households satisfy:

βδb-θπ¯π¯-β(1-δb)>β˜δbπ¯-β˜(1-δb)

The next assumption ensures that inflation is equal to central bank’s inflation target in the steady state.

Assumption 2. The monetary policy tools satisfy:

limtτt^nt+xt=π¯-1π¯
Rn¯+δf<π¯β

We start with the first result showing the relationship between the interest on reserves, the deposit rate and the interbank rate.

Theorem 1. In equilibrium:

  • The lower bound of the interbank rate and the deposit rate is the interest on reserves. In all cases, RtnRtmRtf

  • When the constraint of reserve requirement is not binding, Rtf=Rtm=Rtn.

The benefits of holding reserves come from two sources. First, bankers earn the interest on reserves. Second, bankers satisfy the reserve requirement, showing in the shadow price of reserve constraint μtr0. When the banking system has a huge amount of excess reserves, second benefit is no longer there μtr=0, and the interbank rate is equal to the interest on reserves.

Theorem 2. In equilibrium, the monetary base, as sum of reserves and currency in circulation, is decided solely by central bank:

nt-1+xt-1πt+τ^t=nt+xt (38)

When households withdraw money from their bank accounts, it only changes the level of reserves but does not affect the level of monetary base. We assume that central bank will target the interbank rate, so it implies that central bank will never leave the banking system with the negative amount of reserves.

Theorem 3. Under the Assumption (1)-(2) and if κ satisfies:

κ<1-(1-φ)m¯bh¯

where m¯ is the steady state value of m, then there exists a unique steady state. Moreover, in this steady state, the reserve requirement is binding while the capital constraint is not binding.

This unique steady state reflects the banking systems in US and EU before the Great Recession. There were no excess reserves, and the policy rates were higher than 2 percent. These central banks’ main tool was open market operations at that time, rather than the IOR. After the Great Recession, due to many rounds of quantitative easing (unconventional monetary policy), the excess reserves skyrocketed. However, in the long term, these central banks have a plan to scale down their balance sheets’ size to the pre-crisis level. As a result of that, this unique steady state might properly show the long-term position of those central banks.

Numerical experiments

Calibration

Data are calibrated to match the US economy before the Great Recession (Table 7). Each period in the model is equivalent to one quarter. The bankers’ discount factor is set to the standard value 0.99. The reserve requirement is calibrated to reflect the ratio between the total level of reserves and the total ZMDs. In Dec 2007, before the financial crisis, the total level of reserves was around 9 billion dollars. The total MZM (Money Zero Maturity) was approximately 8130 billion, 75-80 percent of which are checkable deposits, saving deposits and money market deposit accounts. The level of ZMDs was therefore 6000 billion, and the ratio between reserves and ZMD is 0.0015. We round up this ratio to 0.002 and set φ = .002. The monitoring cost and the loan amortization factor are set exogenously. The risk weight is calibrated so that it satisfies the conditions in the Theorem 3 to ensure the unique steady state. For κ ≥ 0.2, the capital constraint is binding in the steady state. Therefore, we set κ at 0.18.

Table 7. Parameter values.

Param. Definition Value
Bankers
β Banker’s discount factor 0.99
φ The reserve requirement 0.002
κ The risk weight 0.18
θ The monitoring cost 0.0005
δb Loan amortization 0.5
Households
β˜ Household’s discount factor 0.985
χ Relative Utility Weight of Labor 0.586
bh¯ The borrowing limit 1.5
Consumption Basket
α1 Share of cash goods in the basket 0.06
α2 Share of deposit goods 0.94
σ Elasticity of substitution between two goods 10
Firms
ϵ Elasticity of substitution of wholesale goods 4
ι Cost of changing price 80
Central bank
π¯ Inflation long-run target 1
ϕπ Policy responds to inflation 1.25
Rn¯ The constant IOR 1+0.25/400
Rn¯+δf The lower bound for FFR 1+0.251/400

The consumption basket is calibrated to match the ratio between currency and ZMDs in the economy. In Dec 2007, the total level of currency was 760 billion. [32] estimates that more than half of US dollar bills are held overseas, so we end up with around 330 billion in currency held by US public. At the same time, ZMDs was 6000 billion, so currency accounts for approximately 6 percent of the total money supply (MZM). We calibrate α1 = 0.06 and α2 = 0.94 to match this fact. The elasticity of substitution between cash goods and deposit goods is set exogenously to 10.

For central bank’s parameters, the only unusual parameter is the interest on reserves. We set it at 25 basis points and consider it as the lower bound for IOR at most cases in our quantitative exercises. All other parameters are in the standard range in the New Keynesian literature.

Shock on the interbank rate

The first numerical experiment is to examine the response of the economy when central bank cuts the interbank rate. The list of equations for monetary policy and exogenous shock is:

Rtf=max{π¯β(πt+1π¯)ϕπexp(utf),Rn¯+δf}Rtn=Rn¯utf=ρfut-1f,u0fisgiven (M1)

From the steady state, there is an unexpected shock on the interbank rate u0f, then agents know the shock will die slowly with the persistence ρf. These two parameters’ values are in Table 8. We can summarize this problem as (P1) containing the set of conditions in (AD) and (M1). Fig 1 shows the response of the economy under this experiment.

Table 8. Parmeter values in experiments.

Param. Definition Value
Experiment (M1)
u0f Initial interest shock -2/400
ρf The persistence of the interest shock 0.7
Experiment (M2)
κ0 Initial shock on the risk weight 0.224
ρκ The persistence of shock 0.95
Experiment (M3)
Rn_ The negative lower bound for IOR 1-0.35/400
Te Number of periods Rtn=Rn_ 50
Experiment (M4)
ϵ¯ The forward guidance signal -1/400
TFG Number of periods in forward guidance 16
Experiment (M5)
ϕm Coefficient in mixed rule 0.2
Experiment (M6)
αn Coefficient in Taylor Rule 0.8
Te Number of periods targeting both MS and IR 50

Fig 1. Impulse response to interest rate shock (M1).

Fig 1

When central bank cuts the interbank rate by increasing the level of reserves, ql increases and the real lending rate rh is lower for households. As bankers lend out by creating money under the form of ZMDs, the money supply increases. It is noting that both currency and ZMDs go up after this shock. The aggregate demand is stimulated and inflation goes up.

Basically, this is identical to the reaction in a standard New Keynesian model. The only key difference here is the role of commercial banks in creating money. Money supply is totally endogenous and depends on the interaction between central bank, banks and public. Another crucial point should be noted that the effect of monetary policy, in this conventional setting, depends on the transmission from the interbank rate to the lending rate in the loan contract between bankers and households.

Financial crisis—Taylor rule

We examine a simple form of a banking crisis by imposing an exogenous shock on κt. This reflects an increase in the bad loans that causes the capital constraint to bind. Central bank is assumed to respond to this crisis by using a Taylor Rule.

Rtf=max{π¯β(πt+1π¯)ϕπ,Rn¯+δf}Rtn=Rn¯κt=ρκκt-1+(1-ρκ)κ¯,κ0isgiven (M2)

From the steady state, there is an unexpected shock κ0. After that, the shock dies with the persistence ρκ. These two parameters’ values are reported in Table 8. We can summarize this problem as (P2) containing the set of conditions in (AD) and (M2).

As the lower bound on the interbank rate is the IOR, the Taylor rule is constrained by the IOR. To see whether the negative IOR helps central bank, we conduct another similar experiment but allow the interest on reserves is negative during Te periods.

Rtf=max{π¯β(πt+1π¯)ϕπ,Rn_+δf}Rtn={Rn_,iftTeRn¯,ift>Teκt=ρκκt-1+(1-ρκ)κ¯,κ0isgiven (M3)

According to [2], the Fed estimates that the interest rate paid on bank reserves in the U.S. could not practically be brought lower than about -0.35 percent to avoid the bank withdrawal. Hence, we set Rn_=1-0.35/400 and Te = 50. We can set the problem (P3) contains the equations in (AD) and (M3). Fig 2 shows the response of the economy under these two experiments. Here are some important remarks:

Fig 2. Financial crisis under Taylor rule (M2) and negative IOR (M3).

Fig 2

  • A Taylor rule with a negative IOR is more efficient than the one with zero lower bound. [25] gets the same result from a standard New Keynesian framework. However, the positive effect is very small at dealing with this type of financial crisis.

  • The banking crisis is dangerous as central bank cannot rely on the pass-through from the interbank rate to the prime rate any more. In our simulation, the interbank rate is at its lower bound for 12 quarters with the IOR at 25 basis points and 4 quarters with the IOR at -35 basis points; however, the real lending rate still goes up. When the capital constraint is binding μtc>0, the wedge between the interbank rate and the prime rate must reflect this shadow price.

  • The banking crisis is often accompanied by the deflation episode and the insufficient demand. Bankers cut loans; therefore, the money supply plummets even though the monetary base increases. In our model, the level of currency goes up a little bit during the crisis. The deposit rate is near zero or even negative in our two experiments, making currency more favorable in households’ eyes. However, this change does not affect much the total money supply because currency only accounts 6 percent of the money supply in the steady state.

  • Lacking liquidity, households cut their own consumption and output declines. A Taylor rule, even with a negative IOR, is not enough for simulating the aggregate demand in this case. When the link between the interbank rate and the prime rate breaks, the conventional monetary policy is generally not effective.

Forward guidance

The recent literature in monetary economics focuses on a forward guidance policy when an interest policy is restricted by the zero lower bound. In this section, we do a simple experiment to see whether a forward guidance policy is useful in the above crisis. There are two common ways to model how central bank informs public about the interest rate path in the future: (i) interest rate peg and (ii) news shock on a Taylor rule. We follow the latter in [30] to characterize a forward guidance policy:

Rtf=max{π¯β(πt+1π¯)ϕπexp(ϵt),Rn¯+δf}ϵt={ϵ¯,iftTFG0,ift>TFGRtn=Rn¯κt=ρκκt-1+(1-ρκ)κ¯,κ0isgiven (M4)

Central bank still follows the above Taylor rule. However, during the forward guidance period 0 ≤ tTFG, central bank commits to lower the intercept of the Taylor rule by exp(ϵ¯). We set ϵ¯=-1/400. In the previous experiment, the interbank rate is bounded by the IOR during the first 12 periods. As a result of that, we set the horizon for forward guidance as 4 years (TFG = 16) to evaluate its efficacy. Fig 3 reflects this monetary policy.

Fig 3. Financial crisis—Forward guidance (FG- M4) and Taylor rule (Taylor- M2).

Fig 3

The key channel that a forward guidance affecting a real economy is to increase the expected inflation. Consequently, it lowers the real short-term interbank rate, which in turn passes through to the real lending rate. In comparison to a common Taylor rule, forward guidance is much more effective at raising the aggregate demand.

The effectiveness of a forward guidance policy depends mostly on the inflation path, which is influenced by the path of the interbank rate and the money supply. Fig 3 shows that when the money supply declines sharply, the effectiveness of a forward guidance policy is limited.

Financial crisis—Mixed rule

The previous section shows that a monetary policy targeting only the interbank rate is not efficient to deal with a banking crisis. What can central bank do to improve the situation? If the main issue is a lack of liquidity in the private sector when banks cut loans, a natural guess should be a policy of targeting the money supply directly. In this section, we examine a modification of a Taylor rule. In normal times, central bank still targets the interbank rate by a Taylor rule. However, in crises, when the interbank rate is near zero and the deflation is still severe, central bank will switch to target the growth of money supply mts=mt+xt. All the exogenous shocks and monetary policy can be described by the following system of equations:

Rtf=π¯β(πt+1π¯)ϕπ(mtsmt-1s)ϕmRtn=Rn¯κt=ρκκt-1+(1-ρκ)κ¯,κ0isgiven (M5)

where ϕm = 0.2 measures the reaction of the interbank rate to the growth of the money supply. The problem (P5) is defined to contain the equations in (AD) and (M5).

We set ϕm small relative to ϕπ for two reasons. First, it means that in normal times, the interbank rate is not influenced much by the growth rate of the money supply. Second, it implies that, in crises, when lowering the interbank rate is not enough for raising inflation, central bank will respond aggressively by raising the money supply through helicopter money. Why? We can rewrite the modified Taylor rule as:

mtsmt-1s=(Rtfβπ¯)1/ϕm(π¯πt+1)ϕπ/ϕm

When the interbank rate is at its lower bound Rtf=Rtn=Rn¯, it means that ϕπ/ϕm shows how aggressively central bank will raise the money supply to deal with deflation. Fig 4 shows the economy’s response under this modified Taylor rule. Here are some important remarks:

Fig 4. Financial crisis—Mixed rule (mixed rule—M5) and interest rate policy (Taylor+negative IOR—M3).

Fig 4

  • When targeting the interbank rate is not efficient anymore, switching to target the growth rate of the money supply is very effective. Both inflation and output paths in this experiment are smoother and less volatile than a Taylor rule with a negative IOR. A modified Taylor rule can anchor inflationary expectations better; thereby restricting the hike in the real lending rate. This result is similar to [33]. Their research also shows that when inflation is out of a bounded region, switching from a Taylor rule to target the growth rate of the money supply can reduce the volatility of the economy.

  • The interest rate path alone does not reflect the stance of the monetary policy. If we only look at the paths of the interbank rate, a Taylor rule with a negative IOR keeps the interbank rate not only longer at the lower bound but also lower in every period in comparison to a mixed rule in this section (Fig 4). If we follow the common New Keynesian logic, inflation should have been higher in the previous experiment. However, this is not the case here. When we model explicitly the microfoundation in the banking sector, the link between the money supply and the interest rate is not as tight as the one in the New Keynesian literature with money in the utility function or cash-in-advance. Central bank does not control the interest rate by directly changing the money supply here.

  • The inflationary expectation is anchored by both the money supply and the interest rate. Seemly, money supply is a more credible signal for the inflation path in economic crises.

Taylor rule and Friedman’s k-percent rule

The new tool IOR allows central bank to target both the interest rate and the money supply at the same time. In this section, central bank is assumed to follow a Friedman’s k-percent rule during our crisis. The following Friedman’s k-percent rule indicates that the growth of the money supply is fixed at a constant level:

MtMt-1=π¯

At the same time, IOR is adjusted following a Taylor rule. The set of monetary policies and the exogenous shock can be written as:

{mtmt-1=π¯πt,iftTeRtf=max[π¯β(πt+1π¯)ϕπ,Rn¯+δf],ift>TeRtn={(1-αn)Rn¯+αnπ¯β(πt+1π¯)ϕπ,iftTeRn¯,ift>Teκt=ρκκt-1+(1-ρκ)κ¯,κ0isgiven (M6)

where αn = 0.8 and Te = 50. Together with the equations in (AD), (M6) sets up the problem (P6). This experiment can be summarized as followings. Before time Te, central bank targets both the IOR and the money supply by, respectively, a Taylor rule and a Friedman’s k-percent rule. After time Te, central bank comes back to its Taylor rule alone. Fig 5 compares the effect of monetary polices in (M6) with the previous experiments: Here are some important remarks:

Fig 5. Financial crisis—Friedman+Taylor (M6) vs mixed rule (M5) vs Taylor+negative IOR (M3).

Fig 5

  • Targeting both the money supply and the interest rate is extremely efficient. The inflation rate is nearly anchored at the target level for the whole time. As our model does not have any real rigidities, it implies the output is also at the steady state level.

  • The byproduct of targeting the growth rate of the money supply is clearly the sharp increase of reserves and excess reserves. Reserves increase by 25 times in our model and the reserve requirement is no longer binding for 25 periods. Many economists worry that a huge amount of excess reserves might prevent the effectiveness of the monetary policy or create hyperinflation. Our model shows these concerns have no foundations. By using the IOR, central bank can control the interbank rate. The effect is very similar to the one when central bank uses open market operations. There are also no reasons to believe the huge amount of reserves will create a huge amount of money supply. When the reserve requirement is no longer binding, we cannot use the logic in the money multiplier model to create the link between the monetary base and the money supply anymore. Until there is still a borrowing constraint and a capital requirement, the endogenous money supply is always bounded.

  • Once again, we emphasize that the stance of monetary policy can only be judged when we observe both the nominal interbank rate, the money supply and the real short-term rate. The money supply and the interest rate can move in any directions. It can be the case that central bank increases the money supply and the IOR at the same time. It might be a serious mistake to infer that it would cause a deflation.

  • The above point raises an important issue about central bank’s communication. In reality, the stance of the monetary policy, when sending to the public, is often summarized by only one indicator: the interbank rate. Indeed, this is a common and good practice as the interbank rate is a unique short-term target that central bank controls completely. In normal times, it is a good predicator of inflation path. However, the current situation is very tricky. The interbank rate in most developed countries has been near zero for a long time, and the inflation is persistently lower than its target. The growth rate of the money supply should be included as a part of central bank’s communication with the public.

Conclusion

With a huge amount of excess reserves in the banking systems, IOR is now the most crucial tool for central banks in developed countries. This tool opens a new monetary policy framework where central banks can target both interest rate and money supply at the same time. Of course, in normal times, adjusting interbank rate alone is always timely and much more transparent than targeting money supply, which is not entirely controlled by central banks. However, in recent economic crises, our research shows that the link between interbank rate and loan rate is very weak. If central banks simultaneously target both interbank rate and money supply, they can hit the inflation targets better.

Mathematical appendix

Proof for Theorem 1:

We rewrite the Eqs (8)(10):

γt=βRtfγt+1πt+1+μtc (39)
γt=βRtmγt+1πt+1+μtc+φμtr (40)
γt=βRtnγt+1πt+1+μtc+μtr (41)

As μtc and μtr are non-negative and γt > 0, we have RtnRtmRtf.

The “=” happens when μtr=0, or when the reserver requirement is no longer binding.

Proof for Theorem 2:

Substitute (32), (35) and (36) into the reserve flows Eq (1), we have:

nt-1+xt-1πt+τ^t=nt+xt

Proof for Theorem 3:

We omit the subscript “t” to denote the steady state value of a variable. Under the Assumption (2) and the result of the Theorem (2) ⇒ π=π¯. Under the Assumption (2) and the Taylor rule (34)Rf=π¯/β. Replace this value of Rf into (8)μc = 0 (the capital requirement is not binding). From (10) and (9)Rm; from (11)ql.

μrγ=1-βRnπ
Rm=(1-φμrγ)πβ
ql=βδb-θππ-β(1-δb)
τ^=π-1π

Under the steady state, (31)pm = (ϵ − 1)/ϵ. Next we move on the household’s equation and can find the steady state of:

(24)λ=χpm
(25)η1=(λ-β˜λπ)πβ˜
(26)η2=(λ-β˜Rmλπ)πβ˜Rm
(27)ηb=ql(λ+η2)-β˜[δb+(1-δb)ql](λ+η2)π>0
(21)bh=bh¯
(3)s=(1-1-δbπ)bh

From (23), we can perform c˜i as a function of c˜:

c˜i=αi(c˜)1-σ(λ+ηi)σ (42)

Substituting (42) into the aggregate consumptions (22), we can find the steady state value of c˜, then c˜1 and c˜2:

c˜=(i=12αi(λ+ηi)σ-1)1σ-1

All the constraints (15) and (17) are binding:

x=πc˜1a=c˜2

From (5), (32) and (16), we can find m and n from the following equations:

[Rm-(Rn-1)φ]mπ=a+δbbhπ-τ^-qlsn=φm

Replacing that into the deposit flows:

i=12ci=m-(Rmmπ+qls+θbh-δbbhπ-x+xπ-(Rn-1)nπ+τ) (43)

From (7) and (4) and use (43):

ci=αic1-σγσc1-σγσ(α1+α2)=c1+c2ci=αi(c1+c2)α1+α2c=[i=12αi1/σciσ-1σ]σσ-1

We know that this steady state only exists if κ satisfy the condition such that capital constraint is not binding, so we need the condition:

κ<1-(1-φ)mbh¯

System of equations in equilibrium

Bankers:

γt=(αictci,t)1/σ1ct,i=1,2 (44)
γt=βRtfγt+1πt+1+μtc (45)
γt=βRtmγt+1πt+1+μtc+φμtr (46)
γt=βRtnγt+1πt+1+μtc+μtr (47)
(qtl+θ)γt=β[δb+(1-δb)qt+1l]γt+1πt+1+(1-κ)μtc (48)
nt-1πt+xt-1πt+τ^t=nt+xt (49)
mt=Rt-1mmt-1πt+qtlst+θbth-δbbt-1hπt+c2,t+c1,t-xt+xt-1πt-(Rt-1n-1)nt-1πt+τt^ (50)
0μtr(nt-φmt)0 (51)
0μtc(nt+(1-κt)bth-mt)0 (52)
bth=(1-δb)bt-1hπ+st (53)

Households:

λt+ηi,t=(αic˜tc˜i,t)1/σ1c˜t,i=1,2 (54)
ptmλt=χ (55)
λt=β˜(λt+1+η1,t+1)πt+1 (56)
λt=β˜Rtm(λt+1+η2,t+1)πt+1 (57)
qtl(λt+η2,t)=β˜[δb+(1-δb)qt+1l](λt+1+η2,t+1)πt+1+ηtb (58)
0η1,t(xt-1πt-c˜1,t)0 (59)
0η2,t(Rt-1mmt-1πt+qtlst+τt^-(Rt-1n-1)nt-1πt-δbbt-1hπt-c˜2,t)0 (60)
0ηtb(bh¯-bth)0 (61)

Firms:

1-ι(πt-π¯)πt+ιβ˜λt+1λt(πt+1-π¯)πt+1yt+1yt=(1-ptm)ϵ (62)
yt=lt (63)

Market Clearing:

yt=i=12(ci,t+c˜i,t)+θbth+ι2(πt-π¯)2yt (64)
ct=[i=12αi1σci,tσ-1σ]σσ-1 (65)
c˜t=[i=12αi1σc˜i,tσ-1σ]σσ-1 (66)

Central bank:

Rtf=max{Rf¯(πt+1π¯)ϕπ,Rn¯+δf} (67)
Rtn=Rn¯ (68)

Numerical method

Inequality constraints

There are 6 occasionally binding inequality constraints in our model: the reserve requirement, the capital requirement, the deposit-in-advance, the cash-in-advance, the household’s borrowing constraint and the Taylor rule of central bank. We deal with these occasionally binding constraints by three methods:

Method 1: We apply the method in [34, 35] to transform the complementary conditions into the equality constraints. For example, if we have the following complementary condition:

μtf(xt)=0,μt0,f(xt)0

We create a new variable μ_t and transforms the above conditions into two following equations:

μt=max{μ_t,0}3f(xt)=max{-μ_t,0}3

We apply this method for the reserve requirement, deposit-in-advance and cash-in-advance constraints.

Method 2: For the capital requirement and the household’s borrowing constraint, we apply the penalty method in [36] to avoid the ill-conditioned of the system and deal with occasionally binding constraints. So the utility of banker and the capital constraint will be changed as:

U=logct-ρe4max{μ_tc,0}4nt+btf+(1-κt)bth-mt=-μ_tc

where ρe = 1e6 is the penalty coefficient. When the capital constraint is violated, banker will lose the utility. However, when they get positive net worth, they do not get reward for that. The household’s utility also is changed to deal with the borrowing constraint.

Method 3: For the Taylor rule of central bank, we use the soft max constraint to deal with the lower bound on Rminf=Rn¯+δf so we can still take derivative to solve the system of equations:

ut=Rf¯(πt+1π¯)ϕπRtf={ut+log(1+exp(smax(Rminf-ut)))smax,ifutRminfRminf+log(1+exp(smax(ut-Rminf)))smax,ifut<Rminf

When smax → ∞, the soft max constraint converges to the hard max constraint. We choose the coefficient smax = 1e4.

Dynamics of economy

We solve the perfect foresight equilibrium with the unexpected shock by assuming that after T = 300 quarters, the economy will converge back to the initial steady state. The initial position before the unexpected shocks is the steady state. Basically, we need to solve a large system of equations to determine the dynamic path of the economy. The transform of occasionally inequality constraints in the previous section ensures that every equation is continuous and differentiable.

For every application, we use homotopy method for solving this large system of equation, with the initial point starting from the steady state or the previous result. We use Ipopt written by [37] with the linear solver HSL (a collection of Fortran codes for large scale scientific computation. http://www.hsl.rl.ac.uk/) to conduct homotopy.

In all cases, we can solve successfully the perfect foresight path with the accuracy at least 1e − 9. In some results, only at the last period T − 1, we observe that there is a big switch from deposits to currency while the total money supply does not change much. When we increase the length of periods from T = 300 to T = 1000 the path does not change. We omit the result in the last period to ensure the smoothness of the result.

Data Availability

All code files are available on Figshare (DOI: 10.6084/m9.figshare.14256617.v1).

Funding Statement

The author(s) received no specific funding for this work.

References

  • 1.Bernanke B. What tools does the Fed have left? Part 3: Helicopter money. Brookings Blogs. 2016; p. 11–4.
  • 2.Bernanke B. What Tools Does the Fed Have Left? Part 2: Targeting Longer-Term Interest Rates. Brookings Institution (blog). 2016;.
  • 3. Meltzer A. Limits of Short-run Stabilization Policy: Presidential Address to the Western Economic Association, July 3, 1986. Economic Inquiry. 1987;25(1):1–14. doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.1987.tb00718.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 4.McCallum BT. Robustness properties of a rule for monetary policy. In: Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy. vol. 29. North-Holland; 1988. p. 173–203.
  • 5.Friedman M. A Program for Monetary Stability; 1960.
  • 6.Taylor JB. Discretion versus policy rules in practice. In: Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy. vol. 39. Elsevier; 1993. p. 195–214.
  • 7. Bernanke BS, Gertler M, Gilchrist S. The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. In: Taylor JB, Woodford M, editors. Handbook of Macroeconomics. vol. 1 of Handbook of Macroeconomics. Elsevier; 1999. p. 1341–1393. Available from: https://ideas.repec.org/h/eee/macchp/1-21.html. [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Christiano LJ, Motto R, Rostagno M. The Great Depression and the Friedman-Schwartz hypothesis. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland; 2004. 0318. Available from: https://ideas.repec.org/p/fip/fedcwp/0318.html.
  • 9. Gertler M, Kiyotaki N. Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycle Analysis. In: Friedman BM, Woodford M, editors. Handbook of Monetary Economics. vol. 3. 1st ed. Elsevier; 2010. p. 547–599. Available from: http://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:eee:monchp:3-11. [Google Scholar]
  • 10. Curdia V, Woodford M. The central-bank balance sheet as an instrument of monetarypolicy. Journal of Monetary Economics. 2011;58(1):54–79. doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2010.09.011 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 11. Gertler M, Karadi P. A model of unconventional monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics. 2011;58(1):17–34. doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2010.10.004 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.McLeay M, Radia A, Thomas R. Money creation in the modern economy. 2014;.
  • 13. Benigno P, Nisticò S. Safe Assets, Liquidity, and Monetary Policy. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics. 2017;9(2):182–227. [Google Scholar]
  • 14. Lucas J Robert E, Stokey NL. Money and Interest in a Cash-in-Advance Economy. Econometrica. 1987;55(3):491–513. doi: 10.2307/1913597 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 15. Belongia MT, Ireland PN. The Own-Price of Money and the Channels of Monetary Transmission. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 2006;38(2):429–445. doi: 10.1353/mcb.2006.0025 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 16. Belongia MT, Ireland PN. The Barnett critique after three decades: A New Keynesian analysis. Journal of Econometrics. 2014;183(1):5–21. doi: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2014.06.006 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Bianchi J, Bigio S. Banks, Liquidity Management and Monetary Policy. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc; 2014. 20490. Available from: https://ideas.repec.org/p/nbr/nberwo/20490.html.
  • 18. Afonso G, Lagos R. Trade Dynamics in the Market for Federal Funds. Econometrica. 2015;83:263–313. doi: 10.3982/ECTA10586 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 19. Sargent T, Wallace N. Interest on reserves. Journal of Monetary Economics. 1985;15(3):279–290. doi: 10.1016/0304-3932(85)90016-9 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 20. Goodfriend M, et al. Interest on reserves and monetary policy. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review. 2002;8(1):77–84. [Google Scholar]
  • 21. Kashyap AK, Stein JC. The optimal conduct of monetary policy with interest on reserv. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics. 2012;4(1):266–282. [Google Scholar]
  • 22. Ireland PN. The macroeconomic effects of interest on reserves. Macroeconomic Dynamics. 2014;18(6):1271–1312. doi: 10.1017/S1365100512000934 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 23. Cochrane JH. Monetary policy with interest on reserves. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. 2014;49:74–108. doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2014.09.003 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Keister T. Interest on Reserves. In: Testimony before the Subcommittee on Monetary Policy and Trade. Committe of Financial Services, United States House of Representatives, May 17; 2016.
  • 25.Rognlie M. What lower bound? monetary policy with negative interest rates. Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics, Harvard University (November 23). 2015;.
  • 26. Eggertsson GB, et al. Zero bound on interest rates and optimal monetary policy. Brookings papers on economic activity. 2003;2003(1):139–233. doi: 10.1353/eca.2003.0010 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 27.Levin AT, López-Salido D, Nelson E, Yun T. Limitations on the effectiveness of forward guidance at the zero lower bound. 2009;.
  • 28.Del Negro M, Giannoni MP, Patterson C. The forward guidance puzzle. 2012;.
  • 29. Campbell JR, Evans CL, Fisher JD, Justiniano A. Macroeconomic effects of Federal Reserve forward guidance. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 2012;2012(1):1–80. doi: 10.1353/eca.2012.0004 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 30. Keen BD, Richter AW, Throckmorton NA. Forward Guidance and the State of the Economy. Economic Inquiry. 2017;. doi: 10.1111/ecin.12466 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 31.Ngotran D. The e-monetary theory. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal; 14 (2020-13): 1–41. Available from: 10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2020-13. [DOI]
  • 32.Judson R. Crisis and calm: Demand for U.S. currency at home and abroad from the fall of the Berlin Wall to 2011. International Finance Discussion Papers; 2012. Available from: https://ideas.repec.org/p/fip/fedgif/1058.html.
  • 33. Christiano LJ, Rostagno M. Money growth monitoring and the Taylor rule. National Bureau of Economic Research; 2001. [Google Scholar]
  • 34. Zangwill WI, Garcia CB. Pathways to solutions, fixed points, and equilibria. Prentice Hall; 1981. [Google Scholar]
  • 35.Schmedders K, Judd KL, Kubler F. A solution method for incomplete asset markets wih heterogeneous agents. Available at SSRN 900165; 2002.
  • 36. McGrattan ER. Solving the stochastic growth model with a finite element method. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control; 1996. doi: 10.1016/0165-1889(94)00842-0 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 37.Wachter A, Biegler TL. On the implementation of an interior-point filter line-search algorithm for large-scale nonlinear programming. Mathematical Programming; 2006.

Decision Letter 0

Mikael Bask

28 Jan 2021

PONE-D-20-26141

Interest on reserves, helicopter money and new monetary policy

PLOS ONE

Dear Dr. Ngotran,

Thank you for submitting your manuscript to PLOS ONE. After careful consideration, we feel that it has merit but does not fully meet PLOS ONE’s publication criteria as it currently stands. Therefore, we invite you to submit a revised version of the manuscript that addresses the points raised during the review process.

After you have revised your manuscript, please, let a professional proofread it. Personally, I recommend that you use American Journal Experts (aje.com).

Please submit your revised manuscript by Mar 08 2021 11:59PM. If you will need more time than this to complete your revisions, please reply to this message or contact the journal office at plosone@plos.org. When you're ready to submit your revision, log on to https://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/ and select the 'Submissions Needing Revision' folder to locate your manuscript file.

Please include the following items when submitting your revised manuscript:

  • A rebuttal letter that responds to each point raised by the academic editor and reviewer(s). You should upload this letter as a separate file labeled 'Response to Reviewers'.

  • A marked-up copy of your manuscript that highlights changes made to the original version. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Revised Manuscript with Track Changes'.

  • An unmarked version of your revised paper without tracked changes. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Manuscript'.

If you would like to make changes to your financial disclosure, please include your updated statement in your cover letter. Guidelines for resubmitting your figure files are available below the reviewer comments at the end of this letter.

If applicable, we recommend that you deposit your laboratory protocols in protocols.io to enhance the reproducibility of your results. Protocols.io assigns your protocol its own identifier (DOI) so that it can be cited independently in the future. For instructions see: http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/submission-guidelines#loc-laboratory-protocols

We look forward to receiving your revised manuscript.

Kind regards,

Mikael Bask

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Journal Requirements:

When submitting your revision, we need you to address these additional requirements.

1. Please ensure that your manuscript meets PLOS ONE's style requirements, including those for file naming. The PLOS ONE style templates can be found at

https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=wjVg/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_main_body.pdf and

https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=ba62/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_title_authors_affiliations.pdf

2. In your Data Availability statement, you have not specified where the minimal data set underlying the results described in your manuscript can be found. PLOS defines a study's minimal data set as the underlying data used to reach the conclusions drawn in the manuscript and any additional data required to replicate the reported study findings in their entirety. All PLOS journals require that the minimal data set be made fully available. For more information about our data policy, please see http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/data-availability.

Upon re-submitting your revised manuscript, please upload your study’s minimal underlying data set as either Supporting Information files or to a stable, public repository and include the relevant URLs, DOIs, or accession numbers within your revised cover letter. For a list of acceptable repositories, please see http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/data-availability#loc-recommended-repositories. Any potentially identifying patient information must be fully anonymized.

Important: If there are ethical or legal restrictions to sharing your data publicly, please explain these restrictions in detail. Please see our guidelines for more information on what we consider unacceptable restrictions to publicly sharing data: http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/data-availability#loc-unacceptable-data-access-restrictions. Note that it is not acceptable for the authors to be the sole named individuals responsible for ensuring data access.

We will update your Data Availability statement to reflect the information you provide in your cover letter.

3. We note you have included a table to which you do not refer in the text of your manuscript. Please ensure that you refer to Tables 3 and 7 in your text; if accepted, production will need this reference to link the reader to the Table.

4. Thank you for submitting the above manuscript to PLOS ONE. During our internal evaluation of the manuscript, we found significant text overlap between your submission and the following works, of which you are an author:

- https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/81579/1/MPRA_paper_81579.pdf

- https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/203245/1/1676918205.pdf

Could you please indicate if either of these works have been peer reviewed or formally published?

[Note: HTML markup is below. Please do not edit.]

Reviewers' comments:

Reviewer's Responses to Questions

Comments to the Author

1. Is the manuscript technically sound, and do the data support the conclusions?

The manuscript must describe a technically sound piece of scientific research with data that supports the conclusions. Experiments must have been conducted rigorously, with appropriate controls, replication, and sample sizes. The conclusions must be drawn appropriately based on the data presented.

Reviewer #1: No

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

2. Has the statistical analysis been performed appropriately and rigorously?

Reviewer #1: No

Reviewer #2: N/A

**********

3. Have the authors made all data underlying the findings in their manuscript fully available?

The PLOS Data policy requires authors to make all data underlying the findings described in their manuscript fully available without restriction, with rare exception (please refer to the Data Availability Statement in the manuscript PDF file). The data should be provided as part of the manuscript or its supporting information, or deposited to a public repository. For example, in addition to summary statistics, the data points behind means, medians and variance measures should be available. If there are restrictions on publicly sharing data—e.g. participant privacy or use of data from a third party—those must be specified.

Reviewer #1: No

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

4. Is the manuscript presented in an intelligible fashion and written in standard English?

PLOS ONE does not copyedit accepted manuscripts, so the language in submitted articles must be clear, correct, and unambiguous. Any typographical or grammatical errors should be corrected at revision, so please note any specific errors here.

Reviewer #1: No

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

5. Review Comments to the Author

Please use the space provided to explain your answers to the questions above. You may also include additional comments for the author, including concerns about dual publication, research ethics, or publication ethics. (Please upload your review as an attachment if it exceeds 20,000 characters)

Reviewer #1: The paper addresses an important economic question even more so during the current crisis, where countries may need to increase the money supply to finance unusually large fiscal expansions. However, I think the paper has a lot to be desired to be considered further for publication.

The key question is what are the new lessons from considering an electronic money economy. In this respect, while the author performs a series of exercises, it is hard to see what is the main punchline and what is the main novelty relatively to previous studies. In general, I believe the paper should be streamlined or re-focused on the key-issue, which is to illustrate the implications of electronic money for monetary policy.

1. The literature review has developed in a non-technical way. What does it make the paper similar to the cited literature? And, what does it make the paper different from the cited literature? Electronic money is far from a dense literature in DSGE models. In order to introduce that analysis in the literature on monetary policy, it is needed to be more precise. It is not obvious why monetary policy should take account of electronic money. The author needs to work on his introduction and his related literature sections much more seriously to address these concerns.

2. The author describes the model in too much detail without a clear message. The author puts forward the following three results:

a. Following a Taylor, it is not efficient;

b. Negative interest on reserves or forward guidance is effective;

c. Targeting both interest rate and money supply by a Taylor rule and a Friedman’s k-percent rule, inflation and output are stabilized.

I think that these results can be interesting when thought about separately, but I suggest that the author takes a stand on one main message that he would want to deliver through this paper. Is the paper suggesting that the money supply target is the most desirable out of the policies analyzed? Alternatively, is this paper analyzing the dependence of Taylor rule effectiveness on the interaction with other policies (e.g. money supply targeting)? On the other hand, is this paper about comparing the effectiveness of different monetary policies in presence of electronic money? Once I am convinced with the motivation of this paper, I think choosing any of these three questions would lead to nice contributions. However, crucially, the paper should stick to one question and really nail an answer, before moving onto the next question.

3. The model section should be rewritten by adhering to community standards for DSGE model.

a. Household;

b. Firms (retail and wholesale branches);

c. Banks;

d. Government.

The author should precise what are the components of the model borrowed by the literature and what are those added by the author itself – and, for which reason he adds them.

4. He should clarify why it is crucial taking account of electronic money in order to compare the effectiveness of monetary policies.

Reviewer #2: Reviewer Report

Title: “Interest on reserves, helicopter money and new monetary policy”

Summary: This paper studies the effects of several monetary policy tools (interest on reserves and monetary base) using a nonlinear dynamic model with currency, demand deposits and bank reserves.

I found this paper to be on an important topic and has interesting results. Below I make some comments for improvement.

Main comments:

The paper is fairly well written in the sense that it is clear about what it does. But there are many grammar mistakes. I would suggest having it proof-read.

I found section 2 to be very confusing. I actually think the paper is easier to understand if section 2 is removed and the reader goes straight to section 3. This has the advantage of avoiding repeating equations as in the current version. Any important content in section 2 can be incorporated in section 3.

Remove Tables 1 to 6. I found them confusing and not very informative.

I found the calibration of loan amortization (δb) odd. In section 2.4 it is said that if an agent borrows £1 then the repayment will be:

δ_b in year 1

δ_b x (1-δ_b) in year 2

δ_b x〖(1-δ_b)〗^2 in year 3

and so on…

If one sums the numbers from year 2 onwards then we get:

Sum=δ_b×(δ_b)/((1-δ_b) )

With δ_b set at 0.5 then we get the above is 0.5.

Even if we were to add a discount factor to the above (say β) it would not change much.

Compare this to a perpetuity which has present value of 1/r. If we set r=0.04 then we get 25.

The loan amortization seems to me to be implying an excessively high interest rate (or maybe there is something I am missing here…). I would therefore suggest adopting a different value for δ_b.

**********

6. PLOS authors have the option to publish the peer review history of their article (what does this mean?). If published, this will include your full peer review and any attached files.

If you choose “no”, your identity will remain anonymous but your review may still be made public.

Do you want your identity to be public for this peer review? For information about this choice, including consent withdrawal, please see our Privacy Policy.

Reviewer #1: No

Reviewer #2: No

[NOTE: If reviewer comments were submitted as an attachment file, they will be attached to this email and accessible via the submission site. Please log into your account, locate the manuscript record, and check for the action link "View Attachments". If this link does not appear, there are no attachment files.]

While revising your submission, please upload your figure files to the Preflight Analysis and Conversion Engine (PACE) digital diagnostic tool, https://pacev2.apexcovantage.com/. PACE helps ensure that figures meet PLOS requirements. To use PACE, you must first register as a user. Registration is free. Then, login and navigate to the UPLOAD tab, where you will find detailed instructions on how to use the tool. If you encounter any issues or have any questions when using PACE, please email PLOS at figures@plos.org. Please note that Supporting Information files do not need this step.

PLoS One. 2021 Jul 19;16(7):e0253956. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0253956.r002

Author response to Decision Letter 0


21 Mar 2021

Response to Reviewer 1 on “Interest on reserves, helicopter money and new monetary policy” for PLOS ONE

I thank the referee for reading my work and providing thoughtful and fair comments on it. Below I will outline how I would respond to the referees’ suggestions:

General comments: “The key question is what are the new lessons from considering an electronic money economy. In this respect, while the author performs a series of exercises, it is hard to see what is the main punchline and what is the main novelty relatively to previous studies. In general, I believe the paper should be streamlined or re-focused on the key-issue, which is to illustrate the implications of electronic money for monetary policy”.

My Response:

I am happy to do this in my revised version by emphasizing the contribution of my paper (Introduction- page 2 line 29). With electronic money and interest on reserves, central banks could “simultaneously” move money supply and interest rate in every direction. In textbooks, when money supply increases, interest rate goes down. However, in the electronic monetary system, if central banks want, interest rate could go up when money supply increases.

1. “The literature review has developed in a non-technical way. What does it make the paper similar to the cited literature? And, what does it make the paper different from the cited literature? Electronic money is far from a dense literature in DSGE models. In order to introduce that analysis in the literature on monetary policy, it is needed to be more precise. It is not obvious why monetary policy should take account of electronic money. The author needs to work on his introduction and his related literature sections much more seriously to address these concerns”.

My Response: Like my answer in the previous comment, I will definitely emphasize why monetary policy should take account of electronic money in the introduction (Introduction-page 2 line 29 ).

For the literature review, as there was no dense literature on monetary policy with electronic money, I tried linking my model with most relevant studies. In my revised version (Introduction-page 2 line 62), I will start from the closet literature- New Keynesian. Then how my model incorporates other elements to model an economy with electronic money properly.

2. “The author describes the model in too much detail without a clear message. The author puts forward the following three results:

a. Following a Taylor, it is not efficient;

b. Negative interest on reserves or forward guidance is effective;

c. Targeting both interest rate and money supply by a Taylor rule and a Friedman’s k-percent rule, inflation and output are stabilized.

I think that these results can be interesting when thought about separately, but I suggest that the author takes a stand on one main message that he would want to deliver through this paper. Is the paper suggesting that the money supply target is the most desirable out of the policies analyzed? Alternatively, is this paper analyzing the dependence of Taylor rule effectiveness on the interaction with other policies (e.g. money supply targeting)? On the other hand, is this paper about comparing the effectiveness of different monetary policies in presence of electronic money? Once I am convinced with the motivation of this paper, I think choosing any of these three questions would lead to nice contributions. However, crucially, the paper should stick to one question and really nail an answer, before moving onto the next question”.

My Response: I am happy to explain this important point in my abstract and introduction. Traditional monetary policy only cares on either interest rate or money supply policy separately. Currently, the dominant New Keynesian framework only characterizes a monetary policy by an interest rate rule. My paper shows that an interest rate rule could be in company with a money supply targeting.

I will insert the following sentence in my abstract:

“An interest rate rule policy alone is just a subset of a more general monetary policy framework when central bank can move interest rate and money supply in every direction.”

In my conclusion, I will emphasize the support of my paper on the combination of a Taylor rule and a Friedman k-percent rule.

3. “The model section should be rewritten by adhering to community standards for DSGE model.

a. Household;

b. Firms (retail and wholesale branches);

c. Banks;

d. Government.

The author should precise what are the components of the model borrowed by the literature and what are those added by the author itself – and, for which reason he adds them”.

My Response: I insert this following sentence at the literature review (page 3- line 83)

“The model is very similar to a standard New Keynesian model, except the flows of electronic payments and the banker problem”.

I have to add bankers and reserves into this model to understand the connection between interest on reserves, interbank rate and money supply.

4. “He should clarify why it is crucial taking account of electronic money in order to compare the effectiveness of monetary policies”.

My Response: I am happy to do this in my revised version by emphasizing the contribution of my paper (Introduction-page 2 line 29).

Response to Reviewer 2 on “Interest on reserves, helicopter money and new monetary policy” for PLOS ONE

I thank the referee for a positive feedback and providing thoughtful and fair comments on it. Below I will outline how I would respond to the referees’ suggestions:

1. “I found section 2 to be very confusing. I actually think the paper is easier to understand if section 2 is removed and the reader goes straight to section 3. This has the advantage of avoiding repeating equations as in the current version. Any important content in section 2 can be incorporated in section 3.

Remove Tables 1 to 6. I found them confusing and not very informative”.

My Response:

I separate section 2 from section 3 to separate the environment of the model and each agent’s optimal problem. If my paper followed a standard New Keynesian model, Section 2 would not be necessary. However, transactions with reserves and deposits are not dense in the literature. I hope that my paper will be easily understood for all non-experts, so I trade off between the paper length and details of the environment.

I insert the Tables 1 to 6 for the same reason. Tables 1 to 6 are unnecessary for economists working at central banks or economists specializing in monetary policy. However, many economists who do not fall into the above categories could find them useful. In the case that the editor agrees with the referee, I am happy to move them to the Appendix.

2. “I found the calibration of loan amortization (δb) odd. In section 2.4 it is said that if an agent borrows £1 then the repayment will be:

δ_b in year 1

δ_b x (1-δ_b) in year 2

δ_b x〖(1-δ_b)〗^2 in year 3

and so on…

If one sums the numbers from year 2 onwards then we get:

Sum=δ_b×(δ_b)/((1-δ_b) )

With δ_b set at 0.5 then we get the above is 0.5.

Even if we were to add a discount factor to the above (say β) it would not change much.

Compare this to a perpetuity which has present value of 1/r. If we set r=0.04 then we get 25.

The loan amortization seems to me to be implying an excessively high interest rate (or maybe there is something I am missing here…). I would therefore suggest adopting a different value for δ_b”.

My Response: The nominal sum of loan payment will be equal to 1 if the nominal amount of borrowing is 1:

δ^b+δ^b (1-δ^b )+δ^b (1-δ^b )^2+⋯.+δ^b (1-δ^b )^n+⋯.

=δ^b [1+(1-δ^b )+(1-δ^b )^2+⋯.+(1-δ^b )^n+⋯]

= δ_b/(1-(1-δ^b ) )

=1

Furthermore, the price of loan ql (<1 in the steady state). When banks give loans to households, the nominal amount of loan is $1, but households only receive $ ql. If we calculate the interest of the loan, it will be equal to rh (equation 12), which is equal around to 4.25% in the steady state.

3. “The paper is fairly well written in the sense that it is clear about what it does. But there are many grammar mistakes. I would suggest having it proof-read”.

My Response: I tried fixing grammar mistakes as much as possible in my paper. I also asked one of my colleagues in English department to help me. Hopefully, this revised version could reduce the errors to the minimum level.

Attachment

Submitted filename: Response to Referee Report 2.pdf

Decision Letter 1

Mikael Bask

22 Apr 2021

PONE-D-20-26141R1

Interest on reserves, helicopter money and new monetary policy

PLOS ONE

Dear Dr. Ngotran,

Thank you for submitting your manuscript to PLOS ONE. After careful consideration, we feel that it has merit but does not fully meet PLOS ONE’s publication criteria as it currently stands. Therefore, we invite you to submit a revised version of the manuscript that addresses the points raised during the review process.

The paper must be proofread by professionals. I strongly recommend the use of AJE (aje.com).

Please submit your revised manuscript by Jun 06 2021 11:59PM. If you will need more time than this to complete your revisions, please reply to this message or contact the journal office at plosone@plos.org. When you're ready to submit your revision, log on to https://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/ and select the 'Submissions Needing Revision' folder to locate your manuscript file.

Please include the following items when submitting your revised manuscript:

  • A rebuttal letter that responds to each point raised by the academic editor and reviewer(s). You should upload this letter as a separate file labeled 'Response to Reviewers'.

  • A marked-up copy of your manuscript that highlights changes made to the original version. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Revised Manuscript with Track Changes'.

  • An unmarked version of your revised paper without tracked changes. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Manuscript'.

If you would like to make changes to your financial disclosure, please include your updated statement in your cover letter. Guidelines for resubmitting your figure files are available below the reviewer comments at the end of this letter.

If applicable, we recommend that you deposit your laboratory protocols in protocols.io to enhance the reproducibility of your results. Protocols.io assigns your protocol its own identifier (DOI) so that it can be cited independently in the future. For instructions see: http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/submission-guidelines#loc-laboratory-protocols. Additionally, PLOS ONE offers an option for publishing peer-reviewed Lab Protocol articles, which describe protocols hosted on protocols.io. Read more information on sharing protocols at https://plos.org/protocols?utm_medium=editorial-email&utm_source=authorletters&utm_campaign=protocols.

We look forward to receiving your revised manuscript.

Kind regards,

Mikael Bask

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Journal Requirements:

Please review your reference list to ensure that it is complete and correct. If you have cited papers that have been retracted, please include the rationale for doing so in the manuscript text, or remove these references and replace them with relevant current references. Any changes to the reference list should be mentioned in the rebuttal letter that accompanies your revised manuscript. If you need to cite a retracted article, indicate the article’s retracted status in the References list and also include a citation and full reference for the retraction notice.

Additional Editor Comments (if provided):

The paper needs to be proofread before publication. I recommend the author to use AJE (aje.com).

[Note: HTML markup is below. Please do not edit.]

[NOTE: If reviewer comments were submitted as an attachment file, they will be attached to this email and accessible via the submission site. Please log into your account, locate the manuscript record, and check for the action link "View Attachments". If this link does not appear, there are no attachment files.]

While revising your submission, please upload your figure files to the Preflight Analysis and Conversion Engine (PACE) digital diagnostic tool, https://pacev2.apexcovantage.com/. PACE helps ensure that figures meet PLOS requirements. To use PACE, you must first register as a user. Registration is free. Then, login and navigate to the UPLOAD tab, where you will find detailed instructions on how to use the tool. If you encounter any issues or have any questions when using PACE, please email PLOS at figures@plos.org. Please note that Supporting Information files do not need this step.

PLoS One. 2021 Jul 19;16(7):e0253956. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0253956.r004

Author response to Decision Letter 1


30 May 2021

I thank the editor and two referees for feedbacks on my manuscript. I incorporated these feedbacks into my revised version.

Attachment

Submitted filename: Response to Referee Report 2.pdf

Decision Letter 2

Mikael Bask

17 Jun 2021

Interest on reserves, helicopter money and new monetary policy

PONE-D-20-26141R2

Dear Dr. Ngotran,

We’re pleased to inform you that your manuscript has been judged scientifically suitable for publication and will be formally accepted for publication once it meets all outstanding technical requirements.

Within one week, you’ll receive an e-mail detailing the required amendments. When these have been addressed, you’ll receive a formal acceptance letter and your manuscript will be scheduled for publication.

An invoice for payment will follow shortly after the formal acceptance. To ensure an efficient process, please log into Editorial Manager at http://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/, click the 'Update My Information' link at the top of the page, and double check that your user information is up-to-date. If you have any billing related questions, please contact our Author Billing department directly at authorbilling@plos.org.

If your institution or institutions have a press office, please notify them about your upcoming paper to help maximize its impact. If they’ll be preparing press materials, please inform our press team as soon as possible -- no later than 48 hours after receiving the formal acceptance. Your manuscript will remain under strict press embargo until 2 pm Eastern Time on the date of publication. For more information, please contact onepress@plos.org.

Kind regards,

Mikael Bask

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Additional Editor Comments (optional):

Reviewers' comments:

Acceptance letter

Mikael Bask

7 Jul 2021

PONE-D-20-26141R2

Interest on reserves, helicopter money and new monetary policy

Dear Dr. Ngotran:

I'm pleased to inform you that your manuscript has been deemed suitable for publication in PLOS ONE. Congratulations! Your manuscript is now with our production department.

If your institution or institutions have a press office, please let them know about your upcoming paper now to help maximize its impact. If they'll be preparing press materials, please inform our press team within the next 48 hours. Your manuscript will remain under strict press embargo until 2 pm Eastern Time on the date of publication. For more information please contact onepress@plos.org.

If we can help with anything else, please email us at plosone@plos.org.

Thank you for submitting your work to PLOS ONE and supporting open access.

Kind regards,

PLOS ONE Editorial Office Staff

on behalf of

Dr. Mikael Bask

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Associated Data

    This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

    Supplementary Materials

    Attachment

    Submitted filename: Response to Referee Report 2.pdf

    Attachment

    Submitted filename: Response to Referee Report 2.pdf

    Data Availability Statement

    All code files are available on Figshare (DOI: 10.6084/m9.figshare.14256617.v1).


    Articles from PLoS ONE are provided here courtesy of PLOS

    RESOURCES