Abstract
China’s household registration system (hukou) has created an institutional boundary for the social integration of migrants, but few studies have explored if hukou barriers vary by city. We investigate the value of hukou locality in Shanghai and Shenzhen by comparing their patterns of intermarriage between locals and migrants. We hypothesize that levels of intermarriage reflect the rigidity of the hukou barrier— the likelihood of intermarriage is lower and tradeoffs for local hukou are higher if one city has more stringent hukou policies than the other. Using data from the 2005 mini-census, we find support for our hypothesis. Shanghai, in which internal migrants in China find it most difficult to secure local hukou, exhibits lower levels of intermarriage and lower levels of hukou locality-education exchange between locals and migrants compared to Shenzhen. The findings suggest that the decentralization of China’s hukou system and subsequent varying hukou policies have made hukou locality an increasingly salient factor in shaping migrants’ integration and social inequality.
Keywords: intermarriage, Chinese household registration system, migrant integration, education
Introduction
Institutional arrangements set by nation states and local governments create barriers for migrants’ social integration and have profound implications for social inequality (Choi et al., 2012; Faist, 2016; Qian & Lichter, 2001, 2007; Qian & Qian, 2017). In China, one such pivotal barrier is the household registration system (also known as hukou). The hukou system requires each Chinese citizen to register the permanent residence in one place. Each citizen’s registered hukou is categorized according to two classifications: hukou type (urban or rural) and hukou locality (whether or not the citizen lives in the registered hukou place) (Chan, 2004). Hukou is linked to Chinese people’s access to educational and employment opportunities, health care, and other government-funded benefits, thereby saliently shaping individuals’ socioeconomic attainment and social mobility (Li, Gu, & Zhang, 2015; Lu & Wang, 2013; Song, 2014; Tian, 2003; Wu & Treiman, 2004). As geographical mobility is usually not associated with changes in hukou type or locality (Chan, 2013), most migrants, despite physical residence in cities, are not entitled to full citizenship. They work and live in cities, but are excluded from welfare benefits and social services (Chan, 2004, 2013; Li, Li, & Chen, 2010; Liang, 2001, 2016).
Hukou intermarriage reveals information about social interaction and acceptance among people of different hukou statuses—thus the lack of it indicates strong status boundary (Choi et al., 2012; Farrer, 2008; Kalmijn, 1998; Qian & Lichter, 2007; Wang & Wong, 2017). While the pattern of intermarriage across hukou types (i.e., urban vs rural) is well studied (Gao & Zhang, 2011; Jing, Zhang, & Yang, 2016; Lui, 2017; Qi & Niu, 2012; Wang & He, 2014; Wang & Schwartz, 2015; Wei & Tsay, 2014; Xing & Nie, 2010), only few have explored how hukou locality—another important dimension of exclusion based on hukou—shapes intermarriage patterns (Qian & Qian, 2017; Wang & He, 2014). The hukou system has become increasingly decentralized (Chan, 2013; Chan & Buckingham, 2008; Zhang & Tao, 2012). This means that migrants may have different levels of difficulty gaining hukou in various cities and hukou locality itself has become a status boundary (Liang, 2016). Thus, researching hukou locality can advance the understanding of how institutional barriers influence migrants’ marriage formation and social integration.
In this study, we compare patterns of intermarriages between local hukou holders and non-local hukou holders (migrants thereafter) in two major migrant-receiving cities in China: Shanghai and Shenzhen. Both cities have attracted large numbers of migrants and have the most stringent hukou policies among all Chinese cities (Zhang & Tao, 2012), but the criteria for acquiring local hukou are even more stringent in Shanghai than in Shenzhen (Zhang, 2012). We have two research aims. First, we evaluate the salience of hukou locality in marital sorting by comparing levels of intermarriage between locals and migrants between Shanghai and Shenzhen. Second, we extend prior research on assortative mating by educational attainment and hukou locality (Qian & Qian, 2017) to examine whether spouses engage in status exchange between hukou locality and education and how these two cities differ in status exchange. This comparison provides critical insight into the degree to how local hukou carries differential hierarchical advantages in varying social contexts (Gullickson & Torche 2014; Qian & Qian, 2017).
Theory and Hypotheses
Hukou and Intermarriage
Hukou creates institutional boundaries between hukou residents and non-hukou migrants. The boundaries are twofold: hukou type classifies Chinese citizens into their entitlement to either urban or rural welfare, and hukou locality determines whether or not they have access to welfare benefits and social services at a particular city (Chan, 2013). As for hukou type, urban hukou holders often have better welfare benefits than rural hukou holders; however, urban/rural hukou differences have become smaller as large cities like Shanghai and Shenzhen have urbanized many rural parts of the cities. In terms of hukou locality, local hukou holders often receive more benefits and opportunities than their non-local hukou counterparts. The hukou status—the combination of these two dimensions—serves as one of the most important sources of social inequality in China (Cheng & Selden, 1994; Wu & Treiman, 2004; Zhang, Zhu, & Nyland, 2012; Zhang & Treiman, 2013; Zheng & Wu, 2013).
The recent hukou reforms have gradually undermined the hukou type distinction1, but intensified the role of hukou locality in directing and managing internal migration. In the Chinese hukou system, the central government plays a major role in determining hukou-type conversion and the welfare benefits associated with each hukou type, whereas local governments are increasingly responsible for policies associated with hukou locality (Chan and Buckingham, 2008). Since the 1990s, local governments have gained more autonomy to adjust hukou policies under their jurisdiction, including full discretion to set admission criteria and to define the welfare benefits for local hukou (Chan, 2013; Chan & Buckingham, 2008). Local governments set different admission criteria for acquiring local hukou to direct migrant flows. They also treat those with local hukou for better job opportunities and other socioeconomic benefits, which vary from city to city. In general, it is more difficult to acquire local hukou in cities where fewer welfare benefits and social services are available to migrants (Wang, 2005).
Even though hukou reforms highlight the growing importance of hukou locality in migrant integration, most existing studies of hukou intermarriage focus on hukou type. Studies have suggested that the urban-rural hukou boundary is rarely crossed in marriage formation, as evidenced by the low levels of intermarriage between urban and rural hukou holders (Gao & Zhang, 2011; Jing, Zhang, & Yang, 2016; Wang & He, 2014; Wei & Tsay, 2014; Xing & Nie, 2010). The importance of hukou type in the marriage market has persisted since the economic reform in the 1980s (Li & Lu, 2008; Qi & Niu, 2012), while some evidence suggests the intermarriages across hukou types have increased in recent years (Lui, 2017; Wang & Schwartz, 2015).
Only a few studies have examined how hukou locality shapes intermarriage patterns, but they fail to account for the variation of hukou policies at the city level. For example, Wang and He (2014) find hukou locality intermarriage is lower in very large cities and provincial capitals and higher in small cities and townships. But as policies with regard to hukou locality varies at each city, using city sizes and administrative ranking cannot fully examine the association between local hukou barriers on intermarriage. Qian and Qian (2017) show that in Shanghai, intermarriage between local residents and migrants is much less likely to occur than hukou-locality homogamy (i.e., marriage that consists of two locals or two migrants); and when intermarriage occurs, local hukou is in fact a valuable resource for local residents in exchange for migrant spouses’ educational attainment. Yet their study focuses exclusively on one city.
To fill the aforementioned research gaps, the current study investigates cross-city variation in the patterns of intermarriage between locals and migrants. While Qian and Qian (2017) shows that hukou locality is a status boundary in Shanghai marriage market, we extend their research by examining two Chinese cities—Shanghai and Shenzhen—to illuminate how differences in local hukou barriers (e.g., the difficulty to acquire local hukou and the level of welfare benefits associated exclusively with local hukou) are correlated with mate selection. In the following, we first propose the relationship between local hukou barriers and intermarriage, and then describe the hukou policies in Shanghai and Shenzhen and derive the hypotheses.
Local Hukou Barriers
To investigate how local hukou barriers are correlated with mate selection, we build on the theoretical insights from studies of interracial marriage. While race is not the same as hukou, as the latter is not based on physical appearance, race and hukou resemble each other in two major ways (Lui, 2017). First, hukou is detectable through daily interactions by language differences and life styles (Alexander & Chan, 2014; Yan, 2008). Second, hukou status is largely inherited from parents.2 The hukou conversion is theoretically possible, but in reality is very difficult and rare. More importantly, the social construction of race, as well as the adoption of hukou, is to create unequal citizenship and group boundaries when resources are limited (Qian, 1997; Solinger, 1999). Thus, research on intermarriage, by either race or hukou, can shed light on the strength of group boundaries and implications for social inequality (Fu, 2001).
First, we propose that a higher local hukou barrier strengthens the status boundary between residents and migrants, thereby lowering the level of intermarriage. Research on interracial marriage suggests that the likelihood of intermarriage across racial and ethnic groups is inversely related to the strength of group boundaries (Lichter et al., 2007; Lichter, Carmalt, & Qian, 2011; Qian & Lichter, 2001; Waters & Jiménez, 2005). Qian and Cobas (2004) find that intermarriage patterns among Hispanics vary by race and nationality. Latino Whites are more likely than Latino non-Whites to marry non-Latinos; US-born Latinos are more likely to intermarry with non-Latinos than are foreign-born Latinos. In particular, Mexican Americans, who have a longer history in the United States than other Latino groups, have a higher rate of intermarriage with non-Latinos. Similarly, Rosenfeld (2001) shows that intermarriage involving Hispanics or Asians is more likely to occur within the same panethnic group, such as Puerto Ricans marrying Mexicans or Chinese marrying Koreans.
Second, we propose that hukou locality is a valued trait to be exchanged in the marriage market. Research on status exchange within interracial marriage suggests that when individuals marry across group boundaries, they tend to exchange one advantageous status for another one, such as race and education (Davis, 1941; Merton, 1941; Schwartz, 2013). Local hukou indicates eligibility for benefits and opportunities, and thus can be a valued trait in mate selection, sometimes worth as much as education and income (Li & Lu, 2008; Lu, 2003; Xu, 2000). When hukou intermarriage occurs, spouses with local hukou may use their advantageous hukou status to marry hypergamously, with someone of other valued traits (e.g., education).
Specifically, a higher local hukou barrier increases the value of local hukou in the marriage market, which in turn would make hukou more expensive and reduce the probability of hukou locality exchanged for other traits. When assessing status exchange between hukou locality and another valued trait, we focus on education, because it strongly predicts future socioeconomic achievement and is one of the most commonly used indicators in the literature on intermarriage and status exchange (Kalmijn, 1998, 2010). As individuals tend to balance unequal traits in status exchange (Schwartz, 2013), the higher value of local hukou increases the incentive for residents with local hukou to exchange their hukou status for not just higher education but very high education, along with other valuable resources, which results in fewer exchanges because fewer migrants have such resources. Thus, a higher local hukou barrier is likely to be associated with lower probability of exchange between hukou locality and educational attainment.
Third, the status exchange between huou locality and education in marriage formation can also depend on admission criteria for acquiring local hukou set by governments. For example, Choi and colleagues (2012) suggest that the status exchange between nativity and education is weaker in Australia than in the United States, as the former puts more emphasis on skill as admission criteria to the country. If the admission criteria for acquiring local hukou is more heavily based on skill, the status exchange between local hukou and education may differ by migrants’ education, such that trading education for local hukou is less needed for better-educated migrants than for less-educated migrants.
In summary, we make three propositions about the influence of local hukou barriers on intermarriage. First, higher local hukou barriers are associated with lower levels of intermarriage. Second, higher local hukou barriers are related to a lower chance of status exchange between hukou locality and education. Third, if local governments emphasize skills in their admission criteria for acquiring local hukou, the likelihood of status exchange differs by migrants’ educational levels. To test these three propositions, we compare the pattern of intermarriage between locals and migrants in Shanghai with that in Shenzhen.
Shanghai versus Shenzhen, and Hypotheses
Shanghai and Shenzhen provide interesting cases for evaluating the association between local hukou barriers and intermarriage. The two cities demonstrate strong similarities in macro-level context.3 First, Shanghai and Shenzhen have comparable high levels of economic development. In 2005, the GDP per capita was 67,492 yuan (approximately 10,652 US dollars) in Shanghai and 60,801 yuan (approximately 9,600 US dollars) in Shenzhen (Shanghai Statistical Yearbook, 2006; Shenzhen Statistical Yearbook, 2010). Second, Shanghai and Shenzhen are also the two major migrant-receiving cities in China. In 2005, the number of migrants was 4.38 million in Shanghai and 5.76 million in Shenzhen (Shanghai Statistical Yearbook, 2006; Shenzhen Statistical Yearbook, 2010). Third, Shanghai and Shenzhen share high housing prices, thereby putting young people in positions where they face similar structural constraints when making marriage decisions (Davis, 2010). In 2008, the average housing price was 14,099 yuan (approximately 2,226 US dollars) per square meter in Shanghai and 11,143 yuan (approximately 1,759 US dollars) per square meter in Shenzhen, ranked the second and the fifth among all Chinese cities (Livable City Research Lab, 2009).
Despite the comparable levels of economic development, migration inflow and housing price, Shanghai and Shenzhen are different in two aspects of hukou locality conditions that are highly relevant to intermarriage patterns, namely the level of local hukou barrier and the emphasis on skills in hukou conversion. In fact, hukou policies in Shanghai and Shenzhen, which represent two major ways that local governments use to control and direct migration flows (Wu, 2017), are often used as exemplars to illustrate the variation in hukou policies in China (e.g., Zhang, 2012; Zhang and Tao, 2012). Specifically, Shanghai sets higher local hukou barriers and puts greater emphasis on skills in admission than Shenzhen (Wu, 2017).
The higher local hukou barrier in Shanghai is reflected in its entry conditions and the differential treatment between residents and migrants. Hukou conversion—change from non-local hukou to local hukou—in Shanghai requires higher skills, better employment conditions, and longer time than that in Shenzhen. Until 2000, Shanghai did not accept hukou conversion for employment reasons (except for the very talented) (Qiu, 2010). Since 2002, Shanghai has implemented a resident program. This program grants temporary, renewable permits to migrants with at least a bachelor’s degree and stable jobs so that they can access some government-sponsored social services. It also offers a potential path to obtaining local hukou. Permit holders could apply for Shanghai local hukou if they meet additional requirements, such as having paid taxes and social security fees for seven consecutive years, possessing at least a middle-level professional title or technical certificate, and having no criminal record (Xiong, 2013). By contrast, in Shenzhen it is easier for migrants to obtain local hukou for employment reasons. Migrants could acquire Shenzhen local hukou if they had junior high or senior high school education (Zhang, 2012). Shenzhen local hukou could also be granted to migrant taxpayers who had paid sufficient taxes for three consecutive years.4
In addition, the differential treatment between residents and migrants is larger in Shanghai than in Shenzhen. In Shanghai, migrants without resident permits had no access to government-sponsored medical care, unemployment insurance, or pensions, and their children were not allowed to attend local public schools. Migrants with resident permits could access medical care and their children could receive public education from kindergarten to middle school, but they were still excluded from unemployment insurance and the pension system. In Shenzhen, in contrast, migrants were entitled to government-sponsored medical care, and their children could attend public schools. If migrants had paid social security fees for 15 years, they were eligible for the city pension system (Ma, 2005).
As the local hukou barriers are higher in Shanghai than in Shenzhen, the social boundaries and intergroup distance between residents and locals are likely higher in Shanghai than in Shenzhen. Hence, we form the following two hypotheses:
Hypothesis 1: The likelihood of hukou locality intermarriage between residents and migrants is lower in Shanghai than in Shenzhen.
Hypothesis 2: The likelihood of status exchange between local hukou and education is lower in Shanghai than in Shenzhen.
Shanghai also places much greater weight on skills in its admission criteria than Shenzhen. To score migrants, both Shanghai and Shenzhen use a point system, which were launched in Shanghai in 2004 and Shenzhen in 2010. Although the actual score may not apply to our 2005 data, the admission criteria reflect long-standing differences in the cities’ attitudes toward migrants (Zhang, 2012). Shanghai’s point system favors highly educated migrants, while Shenzhen’s point system is more open to all migrants (Zhang, 2012). For example, education credentials from junior high or senior high school are worth points in Shenzhen’s system, but not in Shanghai’s system, where only migrants with at least a bachelor’s degree can receive points. In Shanghai’s point system, migrants receive additional points for English proficiency, computer competence, or scientific skills (e.g., awardees of national competition). Shenzhen’s point system, on the other hand, gives points for volunteering and social service.
Because Shanghai’s admission criteria emphasize more on skills and superior education, the local hukou barriers are much lower for highly-educated migrants than for less-educated migrants in Shanghai. In Shenzhen, the difficulty of hukou conversion does not vary significantly across educational levels. In other words, the differences in local hukou barriers between the two cities are more salient for non-college-educated migrants than for college-educated migrants. Thus, if Hypothesis 2 holds, we expect that,
Hypothesis 3: The difference in the likelihood of hukou-education exchange between Shanghai and Shenzhen is larger for non-college-educated migrants than for college- educated migrants.
To be clear, we do not claim that except for their local hukou barriers, these two cities are otherwise identical for a natural experiment. Shanghai and Shenzhen have different histories and attract migrants from different regions, which may suggest differential language and cultural distance between locals and migrants. These cultural differences are, however, unlikely to drive the hukou-locality-based intermarriage patterns. When Chinese people look for a potential mate, place of origin is not a salient factor but hukou status is quite important (Xu, 2000; Li & Lu, 2008). Additionally, if hukou locality is not that important, as Shenzhen has a larger share of migrant population than Shanghai, we would expect lower levels of intermarriage between migrants and residents in Shenzhen (which is the opposite of Hypothesis 1), given that the influx of (im)migrants tends to reduce the incentive for intermarriage (Qian & Lichter, 2001; Lichter, Brown, Qian, & Carmalt, 2007). In short, although the aim of this study is not to identify the causal effect of local hukou barriers on intermarriage, the remarkable similarities in macro-level context and the key differences in local hukou barriers made the comparison between Shanghai and Shenzhen particularly compelling to illuminate variation in the salience of hukou locality as a status boundary for intimacy (Yu, 2015).
Data and Methods
Data and Sample
To examine these hypotheses, we use the 20% sample of the 2005 mini-census. The 2005 mini-census is a 1% sample of Chinese population and records the population status on November 1, 2005. Adopting a three-stage stratified sampling procedure, the 2005 mini-census collected information on each household member’s gender, marital status, date of first marriage (year and month), educational attainment, hukou type, and hukou locality. As the public-use microdata released by the National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) of China, the 20% sample used in this study is a simple random sample of 2,585,481 individuals and has been used by other scholars to examine marriage patterns in China (e.g., Mu & Xie, 2014).
We restrict our analytic sample to respondents who were living in Shanghai or Shenzhen at the time of the survey (N = 102,756). To acquire an adequate sample size to conduct log-linear analyses and minimize biases from change in education or hukou following marriage and from attrition due to divorce, we limit our sample to 9,052 individuals who were in their first marriage and first married between November 2000 and October 2005 (see Mare, 1991 and Qian & Qian, 2014 for a similar approach). In Shanghai, migrant spouses are eligible for hukou conversion after seven years of marriage, and in Shenzhen, eligibility takes about three years. The application process is generally slow, however, so the actual hukou conversion usually takes longer. Thus, marrying within five years is a reasonable duration to assume no hukou conversion for migrant spouses.
In addition, to examine assortative mating patterns, we need both spouses’ education and hukou locality. As one household may include more than one couple, following Han (2010), we use information on the respondent’s year and month of first marriage to pair wives and husbands within each household. When creating the match-couple sample, we exclude 3,966 individuals whose spouse was not present in the 20% sample. Note that dropping these individuals will not cause bias to our analysis, because whether both spouses were selected or not was determined entirely by simple random sampling done by NBS. We also exclude nine “same sex” couples (the existence of these couples is likely due to measurement errors considering that same-sex marriage is illegal in China). Our matched couple sample consists of 2,534 heterosexual couples, with 1,817 couples in Shanghai and 717 couples in Shenzhen. There is no missing data on either hukou locality or educational attainment.
Method
We use log-linear models to compare patterns of intermarriage by hukou locality and hukou locality-education exchange between Shanghai and Shenzhen (Gullickson & Torche, 2014; Qian & Lichter, 2007). Log-linear models allow us to examine the associations between husbands’ and wives’ educations and hukou locality statuses while controlling for the marginal distributions of these two characteristics. The log-linear model used here is constructed from five-way contingency tables of city (c), husband’s hukou locality (z), wife’s hukou locality (j), husband’s education (k), and wife’s education (l). We code Shanghai as the reference group (Shanghai = 0; Shenzhen = 1). Based on whether individuals had local hukou, we classify them into two categories: non-local hukou migrants (0) and locals (1). Education is grouped into three levels: less than high school (1), high school (2), and some college or more (3), with less than high school as the reference category.
We begin with a baseline model in which educational assortative mating and hukou locality assortative mating are independent from each other. Formally, the model is
(1) |
Fcijkl denotes the expected number of marriages between men with hukou locality i and education k and women with hukou locality j and education l in city c. This model includes marginal distributions of education and hukou locality (λi, λj, λk, λl) and their variations by city, associations between education and hukou locality of each spouse (λik, λjl), a hukou homogamy parameter (λij) and four interaction terms that measure the associations between the husband’s and wife’s educations (λkl). Hukou homogamy is coded 1 if the husband’s hukou locality is the same as the wife’s hukou locality (i.e., husband and wife are both migrants or are both locals) and 0 if the husband and wife have different hukou locality status (i.e., intermarriage between a migrant and local). The associations between spouses’ education levels are measured through full interaction terms between the husband’s and wife’s education (two dummy variables for each spouse’s education, resulting in four interaction terms). In short, this model captures patterns of education and hukou locality assortative mating but assumes that the hukou locality pairing of spouses does not differ between Shanghai and Shenzhen and is not associated with the education pairing of spouses.
Next, we add an interaction term between hukou homogamy and city to examine whether the degree of hukou homogamy varies between Shanghai and Shenzhen, and we obtain the following model:
(2) |
In Hypothesis 1, we expect that hukou homogamy is more pronounced in Shanghai than in Shenzhen due to the more stringent hukou policies in Shanghai. In results not shown (available upon request), we found no significant variation by city in education assortative mating (λkl) or associations between education and hukou locality of each spouse (λik, λjl). Thus, to maintain parsimony in our model, we did not include those terms in the following models.
We follow Gullickson (2006) and Gullickson and Torche (2014) to examine whether an exchange occurs between education and hukou locality. First, we measure dyadic exchange by examining how the odds of hukou locality intermarriage change with the education pairing of both spouses (Gullickson and Torche, 2014). Marriage between a migrant spouse and a local spouse can be divided into three intermarriage types, based on their educations: (1) couples in which the migrant spouse has more education than the local spouse (local-spouse-hypergamy, or the local spouse marrying up in education), (2) couples in which the migrant and local spouses have the same levels of education (homogamy), and (3) couples in which the migrant spouse has less education than the local spouse (local-spouse-hypogamy, or the local spouse marrying down in education). We hypothesize that local spouses, especially in Shenzhen, are likely to use their advantageous hukou statuses in exchange for their migrant spouses’ good socioeconomic statuses (captured by education here). Thus, our interest is in investigating whether local spouses are more likely to marry up in education within hukou intermarriage than within hukou homogamy (an incentive to local-spouse-hypergamy), whether local spouses are less likely to marry down in education within hukou intermarriage than within hukou homogamy (a disincentive to local-spouse-hypogamy), and whether the dyadic exchange varies by city.
The incentive to local-spouse-hypergamy and the disincentive to local-spouse-hypogamy are both measured relative to homogamy. This model can be expressed as follows:
(3) |
When i equals j (hukou homogamy), both xijkl and yijkl equal 0. xijkl indicates local-spouse-hypergamy (migrant spouse is more educated than local spouse), and yijkl indicates local-spouse-hypogamy (migrant spouse is less educated than local spouse). Thus, when i equals 0 and j equals 1 (migrant husband and local wife), xijkl equals 1 if k > l and 0 otherwise, yijkl equals 1 if k < l and 0 otherwise. When i equals 1 and j equals 0 (local husband and migrant wife), these assignments are reversed. The expectation is that τ will be positive and γ will be negative, because the former parameter symbolizes the incentive to local-spouse-hypergamy and the latter parameter symbolizes the disincentive to local-spouse-hypogamy. Further, we expect τ and γ to be less pronounced in Shanghai than in Shenzhen.
Next, we measure market exchange by examining how the odds of hukou intermarriage change with each spouse’s education (Gullickson and Torche, 2014), and we further examine variation in market exchange between the two cities.
(4) |
When i equals j (hukou homogamy), both upij and wqij equal 0. upij measures the education effects for migrant spouses to form hukou intermarriages, and wqij measures the education effects for local spouses to form hukou intermarriages. When i equals 0 and j equals 1 (migrant husband and local wife), upij equals 1 if k >p and wqij equals 1 if l > q; when i equals 1 and j equals 0 (local husband and migrant wife), upij equals 1 if l > p and wqij equals 1 if k > q.
Thus, this model estimates separately how migrants’ and locals’ likelihoods of marrying across hukou boundaries change as their educations change. Specifically, ηp and δq capture how the log-odds of hukou intermarriage change for migrants and locals, respectively, when moving up one level of education from either p or q (e.g., from less than high school to high school). Positive values of η indicate that the odds of hukou intermarriage increase as migrant spouses’ educations increase, and negative values indicate that the odds of hukou intermarriage decrease as migrant spouses’ educations increase. δ provides the same information for local spouses. We expect η to be positive and S to be negative, and we expect n and δ to be less pronounced in Shanghai than in Shenzhen.
Results
Descriptive Results
Descriptive results in Table 1 show hukou locality pairings of spouses by city. In Shanghai, about 47% of marriages within five years of the 2005 mini-census were contracted between two migrants; in Shenzhen, that percentage was more than 70%. About 38% of marriages involved two local spouses in Shanghai, whereas 15% of marriages had two local spouses in Shenzhen. Clearly, individuals tended to marry within their hukou status group in both cities. In both cities, marriages between a local husband and a migrant wife were much more likely than marriages between a migrant husband and a local wife to occur (13% vs. 3% in Shanghai and 11% vs. 4% in Shenzhen). The percentage of hukou locality homogamy is similar in the two cities. Yet, we should interpret the results with caution, because the share of migrants is different in these two cities. The relative size of migrants and locals creates structural marital opportunities for individuals to seek potential spouses and eventually marry (Hou & Myles, 2007). Log-linear analysis allows us to examine the degree of hukou homogamy, net of the compositional effects, by controlling for marginal distributions of hukou status.
Table 1.
Shanghai |
Shenzhen |
|||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Wives’ Hukou | Wives’ Hukou | |||||
Husbands’ Hukou | Migrants | Locals | Total | Migrants | Locals | Total |
Migrants | 46.56 | 3.14 | 49.70 | 70.43 | 4.32 | 74.76 |
Locals | 12.49 | 37.81 | 50.30 | 10.74 | 14.50 | 25.24 |
Total | 59.05 | 40.95 | 100.00 (N = 1,817) | 81.17 | 18.83 | 100.00 (N = 717) |
We first present the distributions of education attainment for migrant husbands, local husbands, migrant wives, and local wives in each city, respectively, in Figure 1. On average, migrants are less educated than locals, regardless of gender, in both Shanghai and Shenzhen. Among migrants, men are better educated than women in both Shanghai and Shenzhen. In contrast, among locals, the gender gap in education is either small or even reversed: local men on average are only slightly better educated than their female counterparts in Shenzhen, and local women on average are more educated than their male counterparts in Shanghai. Log-linear models control for the education inequalities between men and women and between locals and migrants to capture the associations between spouses’ education and between educational and hukou locality assortative mating, net of the marginal distributions of spouses’ traits.
Log-linear Models
In Table 2, we present results based on a series of log-linear models. In Hypothesis 1, we anticipate that hukou locality intermarriage is lower in Shanghai than in Shenzhen, because hukou policies are more stringent in Shanghai. To test this hypothesis, in model 1, we examine variations in hukou locality assortative mating by city. Recall that we code the cells along the main diagonal as 1 and those off the diagonal as 0 in the cross-tabulation between hukou locality of the husband and wife. Thus, hukou intermarriage in which spouses marry across hukou locality boundaries serves as the reference category and contrast with hukou homogamy. Consistent with Hypothesis 1, hukou locality homogamy is more pronounced in Shanghai than in Shenzhen: the odds of hukou locality homogamy are 5.37 and 3.97 times as high as the odds of hukou intermarriage in Shanghai and Shenzhen, respectively (Shanghai: β = 1.68, exp(β) = 5.37, p < 0.001; Shenzhen: β = 1.68 – 0.30 = 1.38, exp(β) = 3.97, p < 0.001). The significant interaction term between the hukou locality homogamy parameter and the city indicator reveals that the difference in the likelihood of homogamy between Shanghai and Shenzhen is statistically significant (β = 0.30, p < 0.05). Hypothesis 1, which predicts that the level of hukou locality intermarriage will be lower in Shanghai than in Shenzhen, is therefore supported.
Table 2.
Parameters | Model 1 | Model 2 | Model 3 | Model 4 | Model 5 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Hukou homogamy | 1.68*** (0.08) | ||||
Shenzhen * hukou homogamy | −0.30* (0.14) | ||||
Local-spouse-hypergamy | 0.53** (0.18) | 0.54* (0.21) | |||
Local-spouse-hypogamy | −0.23 (0.14) | −0.03 (0.16) | |||
Shenzhen * local-spouse-hypergamy | −0.05 (0.36) | ||||
Shenzhen * local-spouse-hypogamy | −0.78* (0.31) | ||||
Migrants: high school vs. less than high school | 0.33 (0.17) | 0.02 (0.19) | |||
Migrants: some college or above vs. high school | 0.91** (0.18) | 0.95*** (0.23) | |||
Locals: high school vs. less than high school | 0.16 (0.19) | 0.30 (0.19) | |||
Locals: some college or above vs. high school | 0.08 (0.16) | −0.00 (0.19) | |||
Shenzhen * (migrants: high school vs. less than high school) | 1.81*** (0.50) | ||||
Shenzhen * (migrants: some college or above vs. high school) | −0.21 (0.34) | ||||
Shenzhen * (locals: high school vs. less than high school) | −0.72 (0.48) | ||||
Shenzhen * (locals: some college or above vs. high school) | 0.29 (0.34) |
Note: Full models are available upon request. Standard errors are in parentheses.
p < 0.05
p < 0.01
p < 0.001.
In Model 2, we examine dyadic exchange, which measures how the joint education characteristics of two spouses affect the likelihood of hukou locality intermarriage (Gullickson and Torche, 2014). We hypothesize that local spouses are likely to use their advantageous hukou locality statuses in exchange for their migrant spouses’ good socioeconomic statuses, as captured by education attainment here. We expect local spouses to be more likely to marry up in education (local-spouse-hypergamy) within hukou intermarriage than within hukou homogamy. We also expect local spouses to be less likely to marry down in education (local-spouse-hypogamy) within hukou locality intermarriage than within hukou locality homogamy. Consistent with our expectations, we find an incentive to local-spouse-hypergamy and suggestive evidence of a disincentive to local-spouse-hypogamy. Specifically, locals in Shanghai and Shenzhen are 70% more likely to marry a more educated spouse when they marry a migrant spouse than when they marry a local spouse; in other words, the tendency for locals to marry up in education is stronger in hukou locality intermarriage than in hukou locality homogamy (β = 0.53, exp(β ) = 1.70, p < 0.01). Despite being non-significant, the direction of the coefficient for local-spouse-hypogamy is negative, as we expect: locals in Shanghai and Shenzhen are 21% less likely to marry a less-educated spouse when they marry a migrant spouse than when they marry a local spouse; that is, the tendency for locals to marry down in education is likely to be lower in hukou locality intermarriage than in hukou locality homogamy (β = −0.23, exp(β) = 0.79, p > 0.05).
To examine variation in dyadic exchange by city, in Model 3 we add interaction terms between local-spouse-hypergamy and local-spouse-hypogamy, respectively, and the city indicator. We find that the disincentive to local-spouse-hypogamy is more pronounced in Shenzhen than in Shanghai. Specifically, the local-spouse-hypogamy parameter is not significant in Shanghai (β = −0.03,p > 0.05). In Shenzhen, locals are 56% less likely to marry a less educated spouse when they marry a migrant spouse than when they marry a local spouse (β = −0.03 + (−0.78) = −0.81, exp(β) = 0.44, p < 0.01). Thus, we find it a disincentive for local spouses in hukou intermarriages to marry down in terms of education. This finding provides supportive evidence for dyadic exchange. Furthermore, consistent with Hypothesis 2, dyadic exchange appears to be more pronounced in Shenzhen than in Shanghai.
Model 4 examines market exchange (Gullickson and Torche, 2014), and Model 5 examines city variation in the market exchange. Specifically, Model 4 estimates changes in the log-odds of hukou locality intermarriage as migrants’ or local spouses’ education changes from one level to another in Shanghai and Shenzhen combined, and Model 5 estimates how such associations differ between Shanghai and Shenzhen. To facilitate interpretation of results from Models 4 and 5, Figure 2 presents the log-odds of hukou intermarriage for each spouse type when education increases one category in both cities. The education of local spouses does not appear to be associated with their likelihood of hukou locality intermarriage (β = 0.16, p > 0.05; β = 0.08, p > 0.05), whereas when migrant spouses’ education changes from high school to some college or above, their odds of hukou locality intermarriage increase by 148% (β = 0.91, exp(β) = 2.48, p < 0.01). A change in migrant spouses’ education from less than high school to high school does not change their odds of hukou locality intermarriage (β = 0.33, p > 0.05).
In Model 5, we examine whether the relationship between spouse education and the likelihood of hukou locality intermarriage differs between Shanghai and Shenzhen. To facilitate interpretation, we calculate the log-odds of hukou locality intermarriage in Shanghai and in Shenzhen, for each spouse type, when the education level increases. The significance of the coefficients for market exchange in Shenzhen is tested using a post-estimation Wald test.
According to Model 5 of Table 2 and Figure 2, local spouses’ education is not associated with their log-odds of hukou locality intermarriage, and this relationship does not differ between the two cities. As migrant spouses’ education increases from high school to some college or above, the increase in their likelihood of hukou locality intermarriage is similar between Shanghai and Shenzhen. When migrant spouses’ education changes from high school to some college or above, their odds of hukou locality intermarriage increase by 159% and 110% in Shanghai and Shenzhen, respectively, and the difference between Shanghai and Shenzhen is not statistically significant (Shanghai: β = 0.95, exp(β) = 2.59,p < 0.001; Shenzhen: β = 0.74, exp(β) = 2.10,p < 0.01; dif.: β = −0.21,p > 0.05). In contrast, as migrant spouses’ education changes from less than high school to high school, their odds of intermarriage increase significantly in Shenzhen (β = 0.02 + 1.81 = 1.83,p < 0.001) but not in Shanghai (β = 0.02,p > 0.05), and the difference is highly significant (dif.: β = 1.81,p < 0.001).
Overall, in addition to supportive evidence of a dyadic exchange, especially in Shenzhen, we also find supportive evidence for market exchange, because migrants are more likely to marry a local spouse (i.e., to form hukou intermarriage) as their education increases. This relationship is particularly strong in Shenzhen. The results suggest a higher likelihood of hukou locality-education exchange for non-college-educated migrants in Shenzhen than in Shanghai, but a similar likelihood of hukou locality-education exchange in these two cities for college-educated migrants, which supports Hypothesis 3 that the lower likelihood of hukou locality-education exchange in Shanghai, compared to Shenzhen, holds for non-college-educated migrants but not for college-educated migrants.
Sensitivity Analysis: Hukou Type and Hukou Locality
So far, we have considered only intermarriage between locals and migrants, without distinguishing between two hukou types. In our sample, locals are predominantly urban hukou holders whereas migrants mostly hold rural hukou in both cities. Specifically, in Shanghai, about 85% of locals but only about 20% of migrants have urban hukou. In Shenzhen, all locals hold urban hukou, but only about 35% of migrants are urban hukou holders. The systematic difference of hukou type between locals and migrants suggests a possibility of hukou type exchange within inter-hukou-locality marriages. Below, we examine whether hukou type affects our results.
First, we examine the distribution of hukou type among intermarriages of hukou locality. As shown in Figure A1, over half of the couples in which two spouses differ in hukou locality form homogamy with respect to hukou type. This is consistent with previous findings that most Chinese marriages are contracted between individuals of the same hukou type (Li & Lu, 2008; Wang & He, 2014). A gender asymmetric pattern of hukou intermarriage is evident in the Shanghai sample. Among couples involving a migrant husband and a local wife, only 11% are rural-husband-urban-wife couples whereas 86% are urban-husband-urban-wife couples. In contrast, among couples in which the husband is a Shanghai local resident and the wife is a migrant, 45% are urban-husband-rural-wife couples. In other words, when women with Shanghai hukou marry migrants, they tend to marry urban migrants, whereas men with Shanghai hukou who marry migrant women tend to marry rural migrants. In Shenzhen, this gender pattern is less pronounced: 26% of migrant-husband-local-wife couples have an urban wife and a rural husband, whereas 12% of local-husband-migrant-wife couples involve an urban husband and a rural wife. These findings suggest that in Shanghai marriage market, both hukou locality and hukou type structure intermarriage patterns, but in Shenzhen hukou type seems less important. It further supports our findings about hukou barrier being stronger in Shanghai than in Shenzhen.
Second, we did a sensitivity analysis by excluding couples in which two spouses differ in both hukou locality and hukou type. In this way, intermarriages that cross hukou locality do not include any couples that might also engage in status exchange in terms of hukou type. The results (available upon request) are substantively the same. Hukou locality homogamy remains more pronounced in Shanghai than in Shenzhen (β Shenzhen*hukou homogamy =−0.42, p < 0.001). The pattern of market exchange (i.e., migrants are more likely to marry a local spouse as their education increases) remains stronger in Shenzhen than in Shanghai (β shenzhen*(migrants: high school vs. less than high school) 1.11, p < 0.1). Thus, this sensitivity analysis confirms the robustness of our main results.
Discussion and Conclusion
Hukou shapes mate selection in important ways in China’s marriage market. Previous studies suggest that hukou type is a status boundary that is difficult to cross in marriage (e.g., Li & Lu, 2008; Qi & Niu, 2012). Yet, less is known about how hukou locality works in the marriage market. How hukou locality poses as a barrier for migrant integration is a pressing question in the context of massive internal migration in China. The significance of hukou locality as a institutional barrier is likely to grow as local governments increasingly use it to exclude migrants and direct labor flows.
To assess how hukou locality is associated with marriage patterns, we compare hukou locality intermarriage between Shanghai and Shenzhen, two major migrant-receiving cities in China. Our findings suggest that hukou locality is a status boundary in the marriage markets in both cities, as individuals are more likely to form local hukou homogamy than to marry across local hukou boundaries. Compared to Shenzhen, Shanghai has higher local hukou barriers that limit and exclude migrants. Indeed, the level of intermarriage across hukou locality and the status exchange with education are lower in Shanghai than in Shenzhen. Thus, higher local hukou barriers are associated with lower levels of intermarriage between locals and migrants, reflecting migrants’ lower levels of social integration in their receiving cities. Additionally, the results suggest that it is more difficult for migrants in cities with higher local hukou barriers to use their educations in exchange for their spouses’ advantageous hukou statuses. Furthermore, increased education among non-college-educated migrants may increase their life chances under Shenzhen’s, but not Shanghai’s, hukou policies. The lower level of hukou locality-education exchange in Shanghai seems to hold only for non-college-educated migrants, not for college-educated migrants.
As previously noted, we do not consider the comparison of Shanghai and Shenzhen as a natural experiment that allows for estimating the causal effect of hukou locality on intermarriage. Shanghai and Shenzhen has different sociocultural traditions, paths of urban development, and attract migrants from different regions. All these factors may influence how locals evaluate migrants and vice versa in mate selection processes.
Future research can benefit by addressing some limitations of this study. First, due to data limitation, our analysis does not include the size and educational distributions of migrant populations in the two cities. Although log-linear models allow us to estimate education-hukou exchange net of marginal distributions of education and hukou locality, we examine only individuals who got married, similar to prior assortative mating research (e.g., Han 2010; Qian & Qian 2014; Schwartz & Mare, 2005), without fully taking into account the size of the pool of, as well as the educational composition of, potential partners who are able to establish an exchange relationship with locals. Future work could incorporate unmarried individuals who are at risk of marriage into the analysis to gain a more complete understanding of mate selection processes.
Second, our results consider only intermarriage between locals and migrants, without further differentiating hukou type. In our sensitivity analysis, we find a possibility of hukou type exchange among hukou locality intermarriages. Especially in Shanghai, both hukou type and hukou locality structure the intermarriage patterns. However, we cannot further examine this intersectionality due to small sample sizes. In our sample, only a small number of couples married across both hukou locality and hukou type (116 out of 1817 couples in Shanghai and 17 out of 717 couples in Shenzhen). Because log-linear models require a large sample size to obtain meaningful results, our sample precluded us from further differentiation. Our sensitivity analysis further shows that excluding marriages that across both hukou type and hukou locality did not substantially alter our results. Nevertheless, the intersection between urban-rural hukou and local-nonlocal hukou on intermarriage can help us further understand the relative weight of hukou type and hukou locality and how they jointly shape mate selection. Future research with sufficient sample sizes are encouraged to explore the intersectionality of hukou type and hukou locality and their joint influences on intermarriage.
Third, Shanghai and Shenzhen have different histories and attract migrants from different regions that prevent the comparison as a natural experiment. The development of hukou policy is rooted in the cultural traditions of local-migrant relationships, which makes it difficult to ascertain the effect of local hukou barriers on intermarriage net of cultural traditions. Our results suggest that hukou locality serves as a salient status boundary in mate selection and higher local hukou barriers seem to be associated with lower levels of intermarriage and local hukou-education exchange. We leave the task of identifying causal effect of local hukou barriers on intermarriage to future research.
The hukou system has undergone extensive changes since the economic reform. One key question is whether hukou continues to serve as a barrier to migrant integration and social equality. Chan and Buckingham (2008) claim that hukou, particularly hukou locality, continues to play an important role in the context of massive internal migration. Our study is a first step to examine how the local hukou barriers set by local governments shape migrant integration in different cities. This study provides critical insights into the salience of hukou locality as a status boundary in marriage formation, migrant integration, and ultimately the contours of social stratification in China.
Supplementary Material
Acknowledgements
The first and the second authors share primary authorship. We thank Li Zhang, Wen Fan, Kam Wing Chan, Yanjie Bian for their comments and suggestions. A previous version of this paper was presented at the 2016 Annual Conference of Urban China Research Network, Xi’an, China. This research is part of the project “sociological theory and social structural transformation” funded by the “Double-First Class” plan of social science development of Fudan University (IDH3458007). We also gratefully acknowledge the general support from the research fund of the School of Social Development and Public Policy at Fudan University.
Footnotes
In 2014, the State Council has proposed an initiative to abolish the urban-rual hukou distinction. Until 2016, 31 provinces have developed detailed policies to erase hukou-type difference. http://www.xinhuanet.com/politics/2016-09/21/c_1119601737.htm, retrieved on February, 3, 2018.
In 1998, the State Council approved a guideline that children can choose to inherit hukou from the father or the mother (previously, hukou was inherited from the mother) (Fan 2008).
As our data were collected in 2005, we discuss the economic situations and hukou policies in the two cities around the 2000s.
http://www.110.com/ziliao/article-31275.html. Retrieved April 14, 2016.
Contributor Information
Felicia F. Tian, Department of Sociology, Fudan University, China
Yue Qian, Department of Sociology, University of British Columbia, Canada.
Zhenchao Qian, Department of Sociology, Brown University, United States.
Reference
- Alexander P, & Chan A (2004). Does China Have an Apartheid Pass System? Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies 30, 609–629. [Google Scholar]
- Chan KW (2004). Cities with Invisible Walls: Reinterpreting Urbanization in Post-1949 China. Hong Kong: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Chan KW (2013). The Chinese Hukou System at 50. Eurasian Geography and Economics, 50(2), 197–221. [Google Scholar]
- Chan KW, & Buckingham W (2008). Is China Abolishing the Hukou System. The China Quarterly, 195, 582–606. [Google Scholar]
- Cheng T, & Selden M (1994). The Origins and Social Consequences of China’s Hukou System. The China Quarterly, 139, 644–668. [Google Scholar]
- Choi KH, Tienda M, Cobb-Clark D, & Sinning M (2012). Immigration and Status Exchange in Australia and the United States. Research in Social Stratification and Mobility, 30, 49–62. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Davis DS (2010). Who Gets the House? Renegotiating Property Rights in Post-Socialist Urban China. Modern China 36, 463–92. [Google Scholar]
- Davis K (1941). Intermarriage in Caste Societies. American Anthropologist, 43, 376–395. [Google Scholar]
- Fan CC (2008). Migration, Hukou, and the City. In Yusuf S, & Saich A (Eds.), China urbanizes: Consequences, strategies, and policies (pp. 65–89). World Bank Publications. doi: 10.1596/978-0-8213-7211-1 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- Faist T (2016). Cross-Border Migration and Social Inequalities. Annual Review of Sociology, 42, 323–346. [Google Scholar]
- Farrer J (2008). From “Passports” to “Joint Ventures”: Intermarriage between Chinese Nationals and Western Expatriates Residing in Shanghai. Asian Studies Review, 31(1), 7–29. [Google Scholar]
- Fu VK (2001). Racial Intermarriage Parisings. Demography, 38(2), 147–159. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Gao Y, & Zhang X (2011). Marital Status in Recent Years: The Case of Beijing [In Chinese]. Chinese Journal of Population Science(6), 60–71. [Google Scholar]
- Gullickson A, & Torche F (2014). Patterns of Racial and Educational Assortative Mating in Brazil. Demography, 51, 835–856. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Gullickson A (2006). Education and Black-White Interracial Marriage. Demography, 43(4), 673–689. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Han H (2010). Trends in Educational Assortative Marriage in China from 1970 to 2000. Demographic Research, 22(24), 733–770. [Google Scholar]
- Hou F, & Myles J (2007). The Changing Role of Education in the Marriage Market: Assortative Marriage. Canadian Journal of Sociology, 33(2), 337–366. [Google Scholar]
- Jing X, Zhang L, & Yang T (2016). A Feminist Perspective of “Hukou Intermarriages” of Rural Migrants: Research from “P” District in Shenzhen [In Chinese]. Collection of Women’s Studies, 133(1), 30–52. [Google Scholar]
- Kalmijn M (1998). Intermarriage and Homogamy: Causes, Patterns, Trends. Annual Review of Sociology, 24, 395–421. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Kalmijn M (2010). Educational Inequality, Homogamy, and Status Exchange in Black-White Intermarriage: A Comment on Rosenfeld. American Journal of Sociology, 115(4), 1252–1263. [Google Scholar]
- Li L, Li S. m., & Chen Y (2010). Better city, Better Life, but for Whom?: The Hukou and Resident Card System and the Consequential Citizenship Stratification in Shanghai. City, Culture, and Society, 1(3), 145–154. [Google Scholar]
- Li J, Gu Y, & Zhang C. 2015. “Hukou-Based Stratification in Urban China’s Segmented Economy.” Chinese Sociological Review 47(2): 154–76. [Google Scholar]
- Li Y, & Lu X (2008). Homophily in Assorative Mating and Change - Matches in attained and ascribed characteristics [In Chinese]. Youth Studies(6), 27–33. [Google Scholar]
- Liang Z (2001). The Age of Migration in China. Population and Development Review, 27(3), 499–524. [Google Scholar]
- Liang Z (2016). China’s Great Migration and the Prospects of a More Integrated Society. Annual Review of Sociology, 42, 451–471. [Google Scholar]
- Liang Z, Li Z, & Ma Z (2014). Changing Patterns of the Floating Population in China, 2000–2010. Population and Development Review, 40(4), 695–716. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Lichter DT, Brown JB, Qian Z, & Carmalt JH (2007). Marital Assimilation Among Hispanics: Evidence of Declinig Cultural and Economic Incorporation? Social Science Quarterly, 88(3), 745–765. [Google Scholar]
- Lichter DT, Carmalt JH, & Qian Z (2011). Migration and Intermarriage Among Hispanics: Crossing Racial and Generational Boundaries. Sociological Forum, 26(2), 241–264. [Google Scholar]
- Livable City Research Lab, 2009, “City Housing Ranking, June, 2008.” http://www.elivecity.cn/html/chengshifangjia/fangjiapaixing/2.html, retrieved May 14, 2018.
- Lu Y (2003). Household Registration System: Control and Social Difference [In Chinese] (Vol. The Commercial Press; ): Beijing, China. [Google Scholar]
- Lu Y, & Wang F (2013). From General Discrimination to Segmented Inequality: Migration and Inequality in Urban China. Social Science Research, 42(6), 1443–1456. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Lui L (2017). Hukou Intermarriage in China: Patterns and Trends. Chinese Sociological Review, 49(2), 110–137. [Google Scholar]
- Ma J (2005). Study on How to Promote Registered Residence System Reform of Shenzhen [In Chinese]. Journal of Hubei University of Technology, 20(3), 215–218. [Google Scholar]
- Mare RD (1991). Five Decades of Educational Assortative Mating. American Sociological Review, 56(1), 15–32. [Google Scholar]
- Merton RK (1941). Intermarriage and the Social Structure: Fact and Theory. Psychiatry, 4, 361–374. [Google Scholar]
- Mu Z, & Xie Y (2014). Marital Age Homogamy in China: A Reversal of Trend in the Reform Era? Social Science Research, 44C, 141–157. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Park RE (1950). Race and Culture. Glencoe: The Free Press. [Google Scholar]
- Qi Y, & Niu J (2012). The Evolution of Assortative Mating Patterns in the Process of China’s Modernization [In Chinese]. Sociological Studies(1), 106–129. [Google Scholar]
- Qian Y, & Qian Z (2014). The Gender Divide in Urban China: Singlehood and Assortative Mating by Age and Education. Demographic Research, 31, 1337–1364. [Google Scholar]
- Qian Y, & Qian Z (2017). Assortative Mating by Education and Hukou i Shanghai. Chinese Sociological Review, 49(3), 239–262. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Qian Z, & Cobas JA (2004). “Latinos” Mate Selection: Variations by National Origin, Race, and Nativity. Social Science Research, 33, 225–247. [Google Scholar]
- Qian Z, & Lichter DT (2001). Measuring Marital Assimilation: Intermarriage Among Natives and Immigrants. Social Science Research, 30, 289–312. [Google Scholar]
- Qian Z, & Lichter DT (2007). Social Boundaries and Marital Assimilation: Interpreting Trends in Racial and Ethnic intermarriage. American Sociological Review, 72(1), 6894. [Google Scholar]
- Qian Z (1997). Breaking the Racial Barriers: Variations in Interracial Marriage between 1980 and 1990. Demography, 34(2), 263–276. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Qiu G (2010). A History of Migrant Population Management in Shanghai:1840–2000 [In Chinese]. Beijing, China: Chinese Social Science Press. [Google Scholar]
- Rosenfeld MJ (2001). The Salience of Pan-national Hispanics and Asian Identities in U.S. Marriage Markets. Demography, 38, 161–175. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Schwartz CR (2013). Trends and Variation in Assortative Mating: Causes and Consequences. Annual Review of Sociology, 39(1), 451–470. doi: 10.1146/annurev-soc-071312-145544 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- Schartz CR, & Mare RD (2005). Trends in Educational Assortative Marriage from 1940 to 2003. Demography, 42, 621–646. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Shanghai Statistical Bureau, 2006. Shanghai Statistical Yearbook. Beijing: China Statistical Press. [Google Scholar]
- Shenzhen Statistical Bureau, 2010. Shenzhen Statistical Yearbook. Beijing: China Statistical Press. [Google Scholar]
- Solinger DJ (1999). Contesting Citizenship in Urban China: Peasant Migrants, the State, and theh Logic of the Market: University of Califronia Press. [Google Scholar]
- Song Y (2014). What Should Economists Know about the Current Chinese Hukou System? China Economic Review, 29, 200–212. [Google Scholar]
- Tian B (2003). China’s No. 1 Document [In Chinese]. Huizhou, China: Guangdong Renmin Publisher. [Google Scholar]
- Wang F (2005). Organizing through Divison and Exclusion: China’s Hukou System. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Wang F, & He L (2014). Spatial Patterns of Marriage Matching and Marriage Migration among Chinese Labor [In Chinese]. Chinese Journal of Population Science(3), 88–94. [Google Scholar]
- Wang FY, & Wong RS-K (2017). From Reds to Riches: Contemporary Changes of Educational Assortative Mating in China. Research in Social Stratification and Mobility. doi: 10.1016/j.rssm.2017.06.001 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- Wang Y, & Schwartz CR (2015). Intermarriage and Social Exclusion in China. CDE Working Paper, 2015–01. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Waters MC, & Jiménez TR (2005). Assessing Immigrant Assimilation: New Empirical and Theoretical Challenges. Annual Review of Sociology, 31, 105–125. [Google Scholar]
- Wei Y, & Tsay W-J (2014). Social Mobility of Females in Rural China: An Assortative Mating Perspective [In Chinese]. Population Research, 38(4), 75–86. [Google Scholar]
- Wu J. m. (2017). Migrant Citizenship Regimes in Globalized China: A Historical-Institutional Comparison. Rural China, 14, 128–154. [Google Scholar]
- Wu K, & Zhang L (2010). Developmentalist Government and Urban Hukou Threshold: Rethinking Hukou System Reform [In Chinese]. SociologicalStudies(6), 58–85. [Google Scholar]
- Wu X, & Treiman DJ (2004). The Household Registration System and Social Stratification in China: 1955–1996. Demography, 41(2), 363–384. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Xing C, & Nie H (2010). Urban Boy Meets Rural Girl: Infant Hukou, Hukou Reform, and Hukou Intermarriage [In Chinese]. World Economic Papers(4), 1–18. [Google Scholar]
- Xiong Y (2013). The Comparison and Implication of Hukou System Reform in Big Cities: Examples from Shanghai, Shenzhen, Chengdu, and Chongqing [In Chinese]. Probe(4), 142–146. [Google Scholar]
- Xu A (2000). Mate Selection: Fifty Years of Change and Its Causes [In Chinese]. Sociological Research, (6), 18–30. [Google Scholar]
- Yan H (2008). New Masters, New Servants: Development, Migration, and Women Workers. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Yu W-H. (2015). Place Families in Context: Challenges for Cross-National Family Research. Journal of Marriage and Family, 77, 23–39. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Zhang L (2012). Economic Migration and Urban Citizenship in China: The Role of Points Systems. Population and Development Review, 38(3), 503–533. doi: 10.1111/j.1728-4457.2012.00514.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- Zhang L, & Tao L (2012). Barriers to the Acquisition of Urban Hukou in Chinese Cities. Environmental and Planning A, 44, 2883–2900. [Google Scholar]
- Zhang M, Zhu CJ, & Nyland C (2012). The Institution of Hukou-based Social Exclusion: A Unique Institution Reshaping the Characteristics of Contemporary Urban China. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 38(4), 1437–1457. [Google Scholar]
- Zhang Z, & Treiman DJ (2013). Social origins, hukou conversion, and the wellbeing of urban residents in contemporary China. Social Science Research, 42(1), 71–89. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Zheng B, & Wu X (2013). Household Registration, Urban Status Attainment, and Social Stratification in Urban China [In Chinese]. Sociological Studies(1), 150–181. [Google Scholar]
Associated Data
This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.