Skip to main content
Springer Nature - PMC COVID-19 Collection logoLink to Springer Nature - PMC COVID-19 Collection
. 2021 Aug 7;44(2):669–705. doi: 10.1007/s10203-021-00350-x

A revised version of the Cathcart & El-Jahel model and its application to CDS market

Davide Radi 1,2,, Vu Phuong Hoang 3, Gabriele Torri 2,4, Hana Dvořáčková 2
PMCID: PMC8346788

Abstract

The paper considers the pricing of credit default swaps (CDSs) using a revised version of the credit risk model proposed in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003). Default occurs either the first time a signaling process breaches a threshold barrier or unexpectedly at the first jump of a Cox process. The intensity of default depends on the risk-free interest rate, which follows a Vasicek process, instead of a Cox-Ingersoll-Ross process as in the original model. This offers two advantages. On the one hand, it allows us to account for negative interest rates which are recently observed, on the other hand, it simplifies the formula for pricing CDSs. The goodness of fit of the model is tested using a dataset of CDS credit spreads related to European companies. The results obtained show a rather satisfactory agreement between theoretical predictions and market data, which is identical to the one obtained with the original model. In addition, the values of the calibrated parameters result to be stable over time and the semi-closed form solution ensures a very fast implementation.

Keywords: Credit risk, Hybrid models, Credit default swaps

Introduction

Default is the main source of risk in the financial markets. To reduce the exposition to the risk of default investors use credit derivatives, such as credit default swaps (CDSs). They are bilateral agreements to transfer credit risk (on a reference entity) between two parties. The pricing of these derivatives requires to assess credit risk. For this purpose, the financial literature offers three types of models: structural models, reduced-form models and hybrid models.

Structural models evaluate the risk of default of a firm issuing a debt based on one or more variables related to its capital structure, see, e.g., Merton (1974), Black and Cox (1976), Longstaff and Schwartz (1995) and Feng and Volkmer (2012). According to these models, a firm goes bankrupt only if it is in financial distress. Excluding sophisticated versions that accommodate unexpected jumps in the value of firm’s assets and for which analytical tractability is lost, see, e.g., Zhou (2001), structural models are built on the hypotheses that firm’s assets follow a diffusion process and investors are able to observe the true distance to default. These two assumptions make bankruptcy predictable, see Giesecke (2006). In reality, however, the hypothesis of complete information is often violated and investors ask for a premium to compensate the risk of a non-predictable default. As a consequence of this, structural models underestimate short-term credit spreads as confirmed by empirical studies, see, e.g., Jones et al. (1984) and Franks and Torous (1989).

The mechanism that triggers default is different in a reduced-form model. Fully embracing the hypothesis of incomplete information and neglecting any knowledge about the capital structure of a firm, bankruptcy occurs as the first jump of a counting process, see, e.g., Jarrow and Turnbull (1995), Lando (1998), Duffee (1999), Duffie and Singleton (1999), Madan and Schoutens (2008), Schoutens and Cariboni (2009), and Fontana and Montes (2014). The possibility to replicate high credit spreads even for short-term maturities and the mathematical tractability are the main advantages of this approach. Considering default as an exogenous event, dependent only on latent variables, is the main drawback.

Structural and reduced-form approaches can be combined together. The resulting hybrid models offer several advantages, such as mathematical tractability, ability to reproduce high short-term spreads and a structural definition of default. A first example of hybrid model is proposed in Madan and Unal (1998). Employed in Ballestra et al. (2017) for pricing CDSs, it assumes that default occurs at the first jump of a Poisson process as in reduced-form models. However, the intensity of default accounts for structural informations. A similar model is proposed in Madan and Unal (2000), where the intensity of default is approximated by a linear function of the firm’s equity value and of a stochastic risk-free interest rate. Similar is also the structural hazard-rate model in Das and Sundaram (2007), where the equity value follows a constant elasticity of variance process instead of a simpler geometric Brownian motion.1 Starting from the different angle offered by the first-passage default models, Duffie and Lando (2001) and Giesecke (2006) obtain a family of hybrid models by introducing incomplete information about firm’s value and default barrier. A more sophisticated hybrid model is proposed in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2006), where default occurs either when a signaling variable breaches a lower barrier as in structural models or at the first jump of a counting process as in Madan and Unal (2000). The intensity of default of the counting process is a linear function of the risk-free interest rate and of the signaling variable measuring credit quality. The short-term interest rate follows a Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) process, see Cox et al. (1985), while the signaling variable follows a geometric Brownian motion.

In Ballestra et al. (2020), the hybrid model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2006) has been empirically tested by employing a dataset of CDS spreads. The full-fledged version of this model does not allow to have a closed-form solution for pricing credit risk. To simplify the CDS pricing formula, the hazard rate can be assumed independent of the signaling variable as in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003), and to simplify it even more, the hazard rate can be assumed constant. In the latter case, the pricing formula for CDS spreads is available analytically except for the numerical approximation of a univariate integral. The empirical analysis in Ballestra et al. (2020) underlines that the model with constant hazard rate provides a good compromise between goodness of fit and computational efficiency.

In this work, we extend the analysis in Ballestra et al. (2020) by proposing a revised version of the model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) where the short-term interest rate follows a Vasicek process instead of a CIR process.2 In assessing companies’ credit risk, this allows us to account for the impact of negative interest rates frequently observed in the last decade. Then, we derive a closed-form solution for the default probability and a formula for pricing CDS spreads in semi-closed form. A one-dimensional integral only needs to be approximated numerically.

As confirmed by a numerical test, the computational burden of the CDS pricing formula obtained is equal to the one of the CDS pricing formula obtained in Ballestra et al. (2020) by imposing a constant hazard rate. Respect to this latter model, however, the current CDS pricing formula must ensure a superior empirical fitting, which we expect to be similar to the one obtained with the model proposed in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003). To test this conjecture, a calibration procedure using econometric techniques is employed. This procedure is based on the maximum-likelihood estimation of the parameters of the process used to model the short-term default-free interest rate. Then, by minimizing the mean absolute percentage error, we observe that the fitting of the empirical term structure of the CDS spreads obtained with our model is identical to the one obtained with the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003). This result corroborates our conjecture and allows us to conclude that the credit risk model considered here is a valid alternative to the model proposed in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003). Indeed, it ensures the same goodness of fit but it takes a hundred times less CPU time to compute a CDS spread.

In addition, a dataset of CDS spreads observed in the last three years is employed to show the stability over time of the calibrated values of the parameters of the new credit risk model considered here. This analysis is performed by considering the spreads of CDSs written on 142 companies. The companies are divided in three groups according to their S&P rating. The model reveals that companies with high credit rating have a higher equity value, their credit quality signaling variable is less volatile, their hazard rate is lower and their duration gap is positive while it becomes negative when companies with lower credit rating are considered. We also study how the calibration varies across different sectors by grouping the companies according to the two digits NAICS sector code, finding that there aren’t relevant differences in the calibrated parameters across sectors. Finally, we observe that the rise of CDS spreads in conjunction with the COVID-19 pandemic is mainly capture by the intensity-of-default parameters.

The road map of the paper is the following. Section 2 introduces the valuation framework proposed. Section 3 derives formulas in closed form for computing the probability of default, the current price of a survival security and the forward price of a survival security. These results are employed in Sect. 4, where two formulas for pricing CDS spreads are derived. The first one obtained assuming the current valuation framework. The second one obtained assuming the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003). The main differences between the two pricing formulas are discussed. In Sect. 5 an empirical analysis estimates the goodness of fit of the two credit risk models in replicating the curve of CDS spreads. In Sect. 6 an investigation employing historical data shows the stability over time of the calibrated values of the parameters of the proposed credit risk model. Section 7 concludes. Appendix A recaps the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003). All proofs are in Appendix B. Appendix C contains the list of the companies studied, the descriptive statistics of the CDS curves, and the results of the calibrations for selected companies.

The valuation framework

A credit-risk modeling framework is developed by assuming that the market is frictionless and perfectly competitive. Trading takes place continuously. Investors act as price takers and there are no taxes, transaction costs, or informational asymmetries.

The default-free interest rate is supposed to evolve according to the following process

drt=kμ-rtdt+σrt,rtdWrt 1

where k is a real parameter that measures the speed at which the default-free interest rate converges to the long-run average μ and Wr is a standard Wiener process under the martingale measure Q. Concerning the diffusion term, in this work we assume that σrt,rt=σr. That is, we assume that the default-free interest rate follows a Vasicek process (Vasicek 1977). In contrast, Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003), Cathcart and El-Jahel (2006), and Ballestra et al. (2020) model the short-term interest rate as a Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) process (i.e. σrt,rt=σrrt, Cox et al. 1985). Considering the short-term interest rate following a Vasicek process represents the main novelty from the modeling point of view of this work. This novelty allows us to account for negative interest rates, which are recently experienced in the European markets and, as discussed later, it gives us significant computational advantages for the calibration. Figure 1 presents a simulation of the Vasicek and CIR stochastic processes obtained using an Euler scheme. The plot highlights how the main difference between the two is the behaviour when the process approaches zero: while the former can assume negative values, the latter remains always positive and reduces its volatility.

Fig. 1.

Fig. 1

Simulated Vasicek and CIR stochastic processes. Parameters for Vasicek: k=1, μ=0.005, σrt0=0.005, r=0.001. Parameters for CIR: k=1, μ=0.005, σr=0.05, r=0.001. The process is simulated using a Euler scheme with discrete time steps Δt=0.01. For the two models we used the same Wiener process as driver to make the visual comparison between the two models easier

Assuming that the short-term riskless rate follows process (1) with σrt,rt=σr, the risk-neutral price at the current time t0 of a default-free pure discount bond with maturity T is given by (see Vasicek 1977):

PVrt0,t0;T=eAt0;T+Bt0;Trt0 2

where

Bt0;T=e-kT-t0-1kAt0;T=σr22k2-μBt0;T+T-t0-σr24κB2t0;T 3

A firm’s credit quality is measured by a signaling variable denoted by x.3 A higher (lower) value of this signaling variable means a higher (lower) credit quality. Specifically, its risk-adjusted dynamics follows the diffusion process

dxt=αxtdt+σxxtdWxt 4

where α is a real parameter, σx is a real and positive parameter, while Wx is a standard Wiener process under the martingale measure Q and is uncorrelated to Wr.

Given the dynamics of the default-free interest rate and of the signaling variable, default occurs either expectedly at the first time the signaling variable x breaches from above the threshold value xL, also known as the default barrier, or unexpectedly at the jump event of a Cox, or counting, process with hazard rate λr=a+br. Here, a and b are real value parameters and λr is imposed to be non-negative. The intensity of default is therefore assumed to be a linear function of the short-term risk-free interest rate. As shown in Madan and Unal (2000), the parameter b proxies the duration gap of a company. A positive value of b indicates a positive duration gap. In this case, an increase of the interest rate reduces the value of the assets more than the values of the liabilities and the credit spreads are positively related to the short-term interest rate. A negative value of b indicates a negative duration gap. In this case, an increase of the interest rate reduces the value of the assets less than the values of the liabilities and the credit spreads are negatively related to the short-term interest rate.

At the default time, the company defaults on all of its obligations and some restructuring occurs so that the assets of the company are allocated exogenously among various bondholders. Specifically, we assume the so-called recovery of treasury, see, e.g., Duffie and Singleton (1999) and Guo et al. (2008), according to which bondholders receive δ default-free discounted bonds with the same maturity and promised payment as for the original security. The recovery rate δ is assumed constant.

The model that we propose here is closely related to Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) with the only difference being the dynamics of the default-free interest rate (both models are special cases of Cathcart and El-Jahel 2006). The model of Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) however is computationally heavy, and Ballestra et al. (2020) suggest to use a constant hazard rate to balance goodness of fit and computational simplicity. Thanks to the different specification of the interest rate process, in our model we can relax the assumption of constant hazard rate, assuming instead that this quantity depends on the short-term interest rate with no additional computational burden.

A possible drawback exists for the current credit-risk modeling framework. Considering the short-term interest rate following a Vasicek process, the linear model for the intensity of default here employed has the potential of yielding negative credit spreads as hazard rates can go negative. However, as also specified in Madan and Unal (2000) this problem can be mitigated, in practice, by calibrating the resulting model to positive credit spread data over a finite horizon of debt maturities.

The probability to survive

Consider the stopping time τx, defined as the first time the random variable x breaches the default barrier xL. Moreover, consider the stopping time τr, defined as the first time the counting process with hazard rate λr has a jump.

According to the valuation framework in the previous section, td=minτx,τr is the random time of default and Qtd>T is the probability to survive up to time T. Note that

Qtd>T=EQ1td>T=EQ1τx>Tτr>T=EQ1τx>T1τr>T=(I)EQ1τx>TEQ1τr>T 5

where (I) follows from the fact that x and r are independent random variables. Then, by Girsanov’s Theorem and reflection principle, see, e.g., (Shreve 2010, pp. 297–299), we have that

EQ1τx>T=fxt0,t0;T=Nd1T-t0-e1-2ασx2lnxt0xLNd2T-t0 6

where

d1s=lnxt0xL+α-12σx2sσxs 7

and

d2s=-lnxt0xL+α-12σx2sσxs 8

Employing formula (6), the analytical expression for the probability to survive of a firm and the price of a survival security (defaultable bond with zero recovery) are defined in the following Proposition (proof in Appendix B).

Proposition 1

Assuming the hybrid credit-risk model in Sect. 2, we have that

Qtd>T=fxt0,t0;TgVrt0,t0;T 9

where f is defined in (6), while

gVrt0,t0;T=eE1t0;T+E2t0;Trt0 10

with

E1t0;T=bσr22k2-μbBt0;T+T-t0-b2σr24kB2t0;T-aT-t0E2t0;T=bBt0;T 11

and B·;· defined as in (3). Moreover, the current price of a survival security with unitary face value and maturity T is given by

SVrt0,xt0,t0;T=fxt0,t0;Tg~Vrt0,t0;T 12

where g~V is obtained by gV substituting b with b+1.

The price of a survival security in Proposition 1 is the discounted value of the probability to survive when the short-term interest rate follows a Vasicek process.

The formula to price a survival security as well as the probability to survive are both available in closed form as shown in Proposition 1. The forward price of a survival security also admits a closed-form solution. This is a relevant point as the forward price of a survival security is required for pricing CDSs. In the current valuation framework, the forward price of the survival security discounts the promised unit payoff for reasons related to exposure to the hazard of default, as captured by the process for the timing risk of default λr, and multiply it for the probability that the signaling variable does not breach the default barrier xL.

To compute the forward price of a survival security, we consider the forward measure QT as in Madan and Unal (2000), which is the unique equivalent martingale measure under which the values of traded assets discounted by the price of the default-free bond, in this case PVrt0,t0;T, are martingales.

The change of measure density process from Q to QT is given by the Radon-Nikodym derivative which is equal to the price of a default-free bond with maturity T, see, e.g., Brigo and Mercurio (2007) and Madan and Unal (2000). Then, applying Girsanov’s theorem, the QT dynamics for x and r are given by

dxt=αxtdt+σxdWxtdrt=μk-rt-σx2Bt;Tdt+σrdW~rt 13

where Wxt and W~rt are Wiener processes under QT while Bt;T is defined in (3). Since by assumption the signaling variable is uncorrelated to the short-term interest rate, its dynamics does not change when we move from the martingale measure Q to the forward measure QT, i.e. QTτx>T=Qτx>T.

The formula in closed form for the forward price of a survival security is provided in following proposition (proof in Appendix B).

Proposition 2

Assuming the hybrid credit-risk model in Sect. 2, the forward price of a survival security with unitary face value and maturity T is given by

FVxt0,rt0,t0;T=QTtd>T=fxt0,t0;ThVrt0,t0;T 14

where f is defined in (6), while

hVrt0,t0;T=eE3t;T+E4t;Trt0 15

with

E3t0;T=b1+b2σr2k2-μBt0;T+T-t0+1+b2bσr22kB2t0;T-aT-t0E4t0;T=bBt0;T 16

and B·;· defined as in (3).

Pricing credit default swaps

In this section, we consider the problem of pricing CDSs. To this aim, let us consider a CDS written on a unit bond with initial protection time t0, final protection time T (T-t0) is therefore the time to maturity of the CDS), and random time of default td. Moreover, let us denote a CDS spread by Π and let us assume that it is paid continuously. Then, at time t0 the premium leg is given by (see e.g., Brigo and Mercurio 2007, p. 736 and Gündüz and Uhrig-Homburg 2014)

PremiumLeg=EQΠt0Te-t0zrudu1td>zdz 17

where 1· denotes the indicator function. Moreover, let LGD denote the single protection payment (so-called loss given default), operated at the time of default td. According to the assumption of recovery of treasury with recovery rate δ, see again Guo et al. (2008), we have:

LGD=1-δPrtd,td;T 18

where Prtd,td;T is the price at time td of a default-free discount bond with maturity T. Therefore, the protection leg is given by

ProtectionLeg=Prt0,t0;TEQT1-δ1Ttd>t0 19

where QT is the forward measure discussed above. By equating the premium leg to the protection leg and solving for Π, we obtain the so-called CDS par spread (hereafter simply referred to as CDS spread) at the initial protection time t0:

Πxt0,rt0,t0;T=Prt0,t0;TEQT1-δ1Ttd>t0EQt0Te-t0zrudu1td>zdz 20

Assuming the credit risk model in Sect. 2, a solution in semi-closed form for computing the CDS spread in (20) is proposed in the following Proposition (see the proof in Appendix B)

Proposition 3

Assuming the credit risk model in Sect. 2, the CDS spread in (20), that we denote by ΠV, can be computed as follows:

ΠVxt0,rt0,t0;T=PVr(t0),t0;T1-δ1-FVxt0,rt0,t0;Tt0TSVxt0,rt0,t0;sds 21

where FV· is the forward price of a survival security defined in Proposition 2, SV· is the current price of a survival security defined in Proposition 1, while PV· is the price of a default-free pure discount bond defined as in (2).

The one-dimensional integral at the denominator of the pricing formula (21) needs to be approximated numerically. The numerical approximation is obtained by employing a 32-points Newton-Cotes quadrature rule. A numerical test indicates that this one-dimensional differential quadrature approximation ensures the required level of precision when pricing CDSs with maturities lower than or equal to 30 years.4

To test the validity of the valuation framework proposed, the pricing of CDS spreads is also addressed with the credit risk model of Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003). The pricing formula for CDS spreads under the Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) model is provided in Ballestra et al. (2020) and is recap in the following Proposition:5

Proposition 4

Assuming the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003), the CDS spread in (20), that we denote by ΠCIR, can be computed as follows:

ΠCIRxt0,rt0,t0;T=PCIRr(t0),t0;T1-δ1-FCIRxt0,rt0,t0;Tt0TSCIRxt0,rt0,t0;sds 22

where FCIR· is the forward price of a survival security defined in Proposition 6, SCIR· is the current price of a survival security defined in Proposition 5, while PCIR· is the price of a default-free pure discount bond defined as in (24).

To compute the pricing formula (22) the one-dimensional integral at the denominator needs to be approximated numerically. As for the pricing formula (21), the 32-points Newton-Cotes quadrature rule can be employed. In addition to this, the forward price of a survival security must also be approximated numerically when computing (22), see Proposition 6 in Appendix A. Specifically, a numerical approximation of the solution of the system of two ordinary differential equations in (33) is required when pricing a CDS spread under the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003). Such approximation is obtained employing the fourth-order-Runge-Kutta method.

The credit risk model here proposed offers therefore an advantage in terms of computational complexity. This advantage is due to the forward price of a survival security, available in closed form for the valuation framework here proposed and not available in closed form for the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003).

The different computational complexity impacts on the CPU time required to price a CDS spread. Table 1 indicates that a single CDS spread is computed in around two hundredths of a second when the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) is employed. The same single CDS spread requires about a hundredth less CPU time when the valuation framework here proposed is employed. This difference is estimated by using a computer Intel Core i7 CPU, 2.3 GHz, with all the software codes written in Matlab 9.3, and becomes particularly relevant in the calibration phase. In fact, generally tens of thousands of CDS spreads need to be computed for a single calibration.

Table 1.

CPU time for obtaining a single CDS spread

ΠV ΠCIR
CPU time 2.407×10-4s 0.022s

Despite the different computational complexity, the term structure of CDS spreads obtained with the pricing formulas (21) and (22) are very similar. In Fig. 2, for example, two humped curves of CDS spreads are proposed, one obtained assuming a positive duration gap (panel (a)) and one obtained assuming a negative duration gap (panel (b)). For maturities from zero to 30 years, the CDS spreads generated by the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) are equal to the ones generated by the valuation framework here proposed. The same occurs when upward sloping curves of CDS spreads are considered. It is the case of Fig. 3, where the employed values of the interest rate parameters are the ones used in the empirical analysis in the next section. Even in this case we observe that the two credit risk models generate similar CDS spreads independently of the sign of the duration gap. This suggests that the two models predict almost equal credit spreads. The only differences can be observed when the volatility parameter of the short-term interest rate σr takes large values (Fig. 4). In this case, we observe that the CDS spreads related to long-term maturities are higher when generated by the credit risk model here proposed. However, such a difference is observed for values of σr which are far from the ones observed in reality. Therefore, we can conclude that the two models generate almost equal curves of CDS spreads and the goodness of fit of the two models should be similar. This conjecture is corroborated by the empirical analysis that follows.

Fig. 2.

Fig. 2

Term structure of the CDS spreads. Example 1, parametrization with humped curve. Parameters: xxL=2, α=0.01, σx=0.2, r=0.001, k=1, μ=0.015, σr=0.005, a=0.1, δ=0.4. Positive duration gap: b=0.1 (a). Negative duration gap: b=-0.1 (b)

Fig. 3.

Fig. 3

Term structure of the CDS spreads. Example 2, parametrization with upward sloping curve. Parameters: xxL=2.5, α=0.01, σx=0.2, r=-0.005, k=0.170, μ=0.005, σr=0.003, a=0.01, δ=0.4. Positive duration gap: b=0.01 (a). Negative duration gap: b=-0.01 (b). The interest rate parameters are as in Table 2

Fig. 4.

Fig. 4

Term structure of the CDS spreads. Example 3, parametrization with upward sloping curve and high interest rate volatility σr. Parameters: xxL=2.5, α=0.01, σx=0.2, r=-0.005, k=0.170, μ=0.005, σr=0.02, a=0.01, δ=0.4. Positive duration gap: b=0.01 (panel (a)). Negative duration gap: b=-0.01 (panel (b))

Empirical testing of models

We use a dataset of (single-name) CDSs. We consider the credit spreads of CDSs written on bonds issued by 142 European companies. For each company, ten different maturities of CDSs are considered, that is T1=6 months, T2=1 year, T3=2 years, T4=3 years, T5=4 years, T6=5 years, T7=7 years, T8=10 years, T9=20 years, and T10=30 years. The CDS data are obtained from the Thomson Reuters Eikon database. Following Packer and Zhu (2005) and consistently with the assumption of recovery of treasury, we only include CDSs with restructuring clause XR14, i.e. no restructuring. Furthermore, we only collect CDSs written on debts classified as senior unsecured and traded in Euros. The list of all the 142 companies considered in the analysis and the descriptive statistics of the CDS spread curves are available in Appendix C.

Moreover, we also use a dataset of monthly quotes of the Euribor rate. In particular, we consider the monthly observations of the 1-week Euribor rate that we use as a proxy for the default-free interest rate.

These datasets are employed to conduct an empirical investigation. The goal of this investigation is to compare the goodness of fit of the pricing formulas in Propositions 3 and 4, obtained assuming the current credit risk model and the one in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003), respectively.

To this aim, we estimate the parameters of the CIR model (adopted in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) to describe the dynamics of the risk-free interest rate) and of the Vasicek model (adopted in the valuation framework in Sect. 2 to describe the dynamics of the risk-free interest rate) by employing the maximum-likelihood method, see, e.g., Fergusson and Platen (2015) and Ballestra et al. (2016), and using the monthly observations of the 1-week Euribor rate from February 1, 2010 to February 3, 2020. Moreover, rt0 is set equal to the 1-week Euribor rate at the day at which the CDS spreads are considered, that is February 3, 2020. The current time t0 is set equal to 0 for notational simplicity and the estimated values of k, μ and σr2 for the two models employed are reported in Table 2.

Table 2.

Maximum-likelihood estimation of the parameters of the CIR model, first line, and of the parameters of the Vasicek model, second line

k μ σr
CIR 0.0170 -0.0049 0.0031
Vasicek 0.0170 -0.0049 0.0029

Monthly observations of the 1-week Euribor rates for the period from February, 2010, to February, 2020, are considered

To complete the calibration of the credit risk models, the values of the interest rate parameters in Table 2 are employed and the recovery rate δ is set to 0.4. A constant recovery rate equal to 40% is a common assumption in the literature, see e.g. Altman and Kishore (1996), Jankowitsch et al. (2008) and Madan (2014). Then, for each company considered, the remaining parameters of the credit risk models are obtained by fitting the term structure of realized CDS spreads quoted on February 3, 2020. This is done by using a calibration procedure analogous to the one proposed in Hao et al. (2013), Ballestra et al. (2017) and Ballestra et al. (2020). Specifically, the parameters of the model that still need to be estimated, namely x0xL, α, σx2, a and b, are obtained by minimizing the mean absolute percentage error (MAPE) between the empirical CDS spreads and the theoretical ones:

MAPEx0xL,α,σx2,a,b=110i=110Π0,Ti-Πjx0,r0,0;TiΠ0,Ti 23

where Πjx0,r0,0;Ti is evaluated using the CDS pricing formula (21) if j=V and the CDS pricing formula (22) if j=CIR, while Π0,Ti denotes the value observed at time 0 (February 3, 2020) of the spread of a CDS with time to maturity Ti.

The results of this calibration are available in Table 3, where companies are classified into three groups according to their S&P rating. We observe that assuming the valuation framework in Sect. 2 we obtain a goodness of fit almost equal, and slightly higher, than the one obtained by assuming the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003). This result is observable independently of the investment grade of the companies considered. Moreover, the values of the calibrated parameters are very similar between the credit risk model here proposed and the one in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003). This indicates that the two models convey the same information about the credit quality of a firm. These findings are confirmed looking at the results of the calibrations for individual companies (see Appendix C, Table 7, where we report the calibration results for a selection of companies from different sectors, countries, and rating classes). Finally, Table 4 reports the calibration results aggregating the companies by industrial sector, and we see that the calibration exercise gives rather homogenous results across sectors. The values for the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) are not reported for brevity, although they do not show relevant differences from the valuation framework proposed in Sect. 2.

Table 3.

Statistics of the calibrated values and of the mean absolute percentage error (goodness of fit) for the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003), formula ΠCIR, and for its revised version here proposed, formula ΠV

x0xL α σx a b MAPE %
(AAA) – (A-) ΠCIR Average 3.224 0.054 0.237 0.010 1.516 8.53%
Min 2.392 0.023 0.177 -0.013 -2.752 2.39%
Max 4.715 0.120 0.300 0.010 1.873 19.20%
SD 0.589 0.020 0.032 0.003 0.667 2.48%
ΠV Average 3.224 0.054 0.237 0.010 1.506 8.52%
Min 2.392 0.022 0.177 -0.013 -2.804 2.25%
Max 4.716 0.121 0.300 0.010 1.860 19.23%
SD 0.588 0.020 0.032 0.003 0.672 2.51%
(BBB+) – (BBB-) ΠCIR Average 3.002 0.037 0.236 0.009 1.285 8.10%
Min 1.612 0.009 0.101 -0.009 -3.832 0.90%
Max 5.076 0.191 0.300 0.010 1.832 15.73%
SD 0.569 0.024 0.030 0.003 1.069 2.81%
ΠV Average 2.999 0.037 0.236 0.009 1.277 8.06%
Min 1.612 0.009 0.101 -0.009 -3.881 0.31%
Max 4.977 0.188 0.300 0.010 1.822 15.76%
SD 0.558 0.023 0.030 0.003 1.075 2.92%
(BB+) – (CCC) ΠCIR Average 2.589 0.085 0.243 0.005 -3.392 6.79%
Min 1.015 -0.029 0.115 -0.020 -19.872 3.42%
Max 5.035 1.314 0.294 0.010 1.639 10.41%
SD 0.849 0.317 0.047 0.010 7.282 2.18%
ΠV Average 2.583 0.084 0.244 0.005 -3.434 5.70%
Min 1.015 -0.030 0.114 -0.020 -19.946 1.86%
Max 4.936 1.304 0.300 0.010 1.638 10.19%
SD 0.831 0.315 0.047 0.010 7.351 2.39%

For each one of the 142 European companies listed in Appendix C, the parameters are calibrated by employing CDS spreads with maturities 6 months and 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 7, 10, 20 and 30 years. The CDS spreads are quoted on February 3, 2020. Companies are organized in three groups according to their S&P rating. The first group is made of 57 companies characterized by medium and high investment grade, that is credit rating greater than or equal to A-. The second group is made of 68 companies characterized by low investment grade, that is credit rating in the range BBB+ and BBB-. The third group is made of 17 companies characterized by speculative (no investment) grade, that is credit rating lower than BBB-. The statistics of the calibrations are available for each one of these three groups

Table 7.

Calibration of formulas ΠCIR and ΠV for a selected group of companies

Rating Company Model x0xL α σx a b MAPE %
AA Allianz SE ΠCIR 3.505 0.064 0.247 0.010 1.673 9.16%
ΠV 3.506 0.064 0.247 0.010 1.665 9.18%
AA- Shell PLC ΠCIR 2.941 0.041 0.219 0.010 1.790 11.20%
ΠV 2.940 0.041 0.219 0.010 1.775 11.22%
A+ BNP Paribas SA ΠCIR 4.405 0.086 0.300 0.010 1.647 10.74%
ΠV 4.406 0.086 0.300 0.010 1.634 10.75%
A Banco Santander SA ΠCIR 2.743 0.052 0.214 0.010 1.669 6.68%
ΠV 2.743 0.052 0.214 0.010 1.660 6.70%
A- Daimler AG ΠCIR 2.600 0.023 0.210 0.010 1.456 6.63%
ΠV 2.600 0.023 0.210 0.010 1.443 6.65%
BBB+ Deutsche Telekom AG ΠCIR 3.860 0.074 0.292 0.010 1.690 7.58%
ΠV 3.860 0.074 0.292 0.010 1.683 7.59%
BBB Banco Sabadell SA ΠCIR 2.929 0.042 0.262 0.010 1.350 9.37%
ΠV 2.927 0.042 0.262 0.010 1.345 9.38%
BBB- Edison SpA ΠCIR 2.600 0.042 0.216 0.010 1.583 4.60%
ΠV 2.599 0.042 0.216 0.010 1.573 4.60%
BB+ Leonardo SpA ΠCIR 2.710 0.020 0.237 0.010 1.600 7.55%
ΠV 2.712 0.020 0.237 0.010 1.601 7.54%
B Selecta BV ΠCIR 2.441 -0.006 0.265 0.010 0.629 4.84%
ΠV 2.444 -0.006 0.266 0.010 0.686 4.85%

The calibration is performed by fitting the curves of CDS spreads. Maturities: 6 months and 1, 2, 3, 5, 7, 10, 20 and 30 years. The CDS spreads used are quoted on February 3, 2020. The CDSs employed have the following features. Restructuring clause: XR14. Seniority: Senior unsecured. The rating is by S&P. ΠCIR indicates the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003), that is theoretical values obtained using formula (22). ΠV indicates the valuation framework here proposed, that is theoretical values obtained using formula (21). Thomson Reuters Eikon is our data provider. The calibrated values for all the other companies considered in the analysis are not reported for brevity, and are available upon request

Table 4.

Statistics of the calibrated values for the credit risk model here proposed (formula ΠV)

x0xL α σx a b λ MAPE %
Finance and Insurance Average 3.027 0.081 0.237 0.009 0.499 0.006 8.30%
Min 1.015 - 0.012 0.101 - 0.020 - 17.171 0.000 0.30%
Max 4.574 1.304 0.300 0.010 1.747 0.099 15.80%
SD 0.734 0.187 0.042 0.004 3.671 0.004 3.10%
Manufacturing Average 2.990 0.038 0.234 0.010 1.577 0.001 8.20%
Min 2.392 - 0.012 0.177 0.010 0.003 0.000 4.90%
Max 4.716 0.078 0.300 0.010 1.837 0.009 13.10%
SD 0.435 0.019 0.025 0 0.363 0.001 2.10%
Information Average 3.300 0.037 0.251 0.008 1.065 0.002 8.70%
Min 2.636 0.005 0.198 - 0.009 - 3.881 0.000 1.50%
Max 4.977 0.074 0.300 0.010 1.813 0.010 14.80%
SD 0.674 0.021 0.032 0.006 1.580 0.002 3.10%
Utilities Average 3.038 0.037 0.232 0.010 1.668 0.001 7.50%
Min 2.472 0.013 0.192 0.010 1.494 0.000 4.60%
Max 4.140 0.062 0.287 0.010 1.795 0.002 9.10%
SD 0.474 0.013 0.027 0 0.000 0.101 1.50%
Transportation and Warehousing Average 2.941 0.032 0.233 0.004 - 3.231 0.020 7.20%
Min 1.635 0.010 0.185 - 0.020 - 19.946 0.000 2.50%
Max 4.936 0.063 0.300 0.010 1.860 0.100 19.20%
SD 1.064 0.018 0.037 0.012 8.655 0.037 5.80%
Others Average 3.033 0.027 0.243 0.008 0.748 0.004 7.10%
Min 2.131 - 0.030 0.200 - 0.013 - 3.881 0.000 1.50%
Max 4.977 0.058 0.289 0.010 1.831 0.024 11.20%
SD 0.636 0.022 0.027 0.006 1.750 0.006 2.40%

For each one of the 142 European companies listed in Appendix C, the parameters are calibrated by employing CDS spreads with maturities 6 months and 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 7, 10, 20 and 30 years. The CDS spreads are quoted on February 3, 2020. Companies are organized in six groups according to the two digits 2017 NAICS sector code (see https://www.census.gov/naics/). The statistics of the calibrations are available for each one of these six groups

Then, we can conclude that considering a Vasicek process (as in the current valuation framework) instead of a CIR process (as in Cathcart and El-Jahel 2003) for modeling the short-term interest rate allows us to preserve (eventually improve) the goodness of fit, as well as to account for negative interest rates and to reduce the computational time required for the calibrations. As specified in Table 1, the gain in terms of CPU time is of about hundred times. Specifically, employing the proposed valuation framework, that is pricing formula (21), the time for calibrating a set of 142 term structure of CDS spreads is equal to 13 minutes and 22 seconds (802s), while employing the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003), that is pricing formula (22), the same set of term structure of CDS spreads needs 20 hours, 11 minutes and 47 seconds (72707s) to be calibrated.

To bring the investigation into perspective, a comparison with the results in Ballestra et al. (2020) is required. In fact, the empirical testing conducted in Ballestra et al. (2020) considers: 1) The credit risk model proposed in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003), which is the model here considered when the short-term interest rate follows a CIR process; 2) The advanced version of this model proposed in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2006), where the hazard rate also depends on the signaling process; 3) The credit risk model as the one here considered but with constant hazard rate; 4) The credit risk model as the one here considered but with zero hazard rate.

The results in Ballestra et al. (2020) underline that an evaluation framework as the one here considered but with constant hazard rate, i.e. b set equal to zero, represents a good compromise between goodness of fit and computational simplicity. Despite so, the same results indicate that the assumption of a constant hazard rate reduces the level of precision. On average, the reduction is estimated in a point of the mean absolute percentage error. This gap of goodness of fit is obtained by employing a set of 65 term structures of CDS spreads, which are made of only seven maturities, that is 1 year, 2 years, 3 years, 4 years, 5 years, 7 years and 10 years. Therefore, the gap is expected to be larger when, as in the current analysis, the further maturities of 6 months, 20 years and 30 years are considered.

These empirical findings compared to those obtained here lead us to a clear conclusion. The credit risk model here proposed matches the goodness of fit of the model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) and, at the same time, ensures the same computational efficiency of the model with constant hazard rate.

All this confirms and enforces our conjecture. That is, assuming that the short-term interest rate follows a Vasicek process instead of a CIR process, we obtain a valid alternative to the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003). Computational efficiency and high goodness of fit make the proposed model particularly useful for practitioners.

Historical calibration of CDS curves

The credit risk model here considered is calibrated by using historical data. In particular, we employ the same set of 142 companies employed above but we consider the term structures of CDS spreads on three different dates, that is February 3, 2020, February 1, 2019 and February 1, 2018. The calibration procedure is analogous to the one used above. For each of these three dates, we obtain the maximum-likelihood estimation of the parameters of the Vasicek model using the monthly observations of the 1-week Euribor rate in the previous ten years. The current value of the default-free interest rate is set equal to the 1-week Euribor rate observed on the day the term structure of CDS spread is considered and the recovery rate is set to 40%. The remaining parameters are calibrated company by company by minimizing the mean absolute percentage error as in (23).

The statistics of the calibrations are available in Table 5. They indicate the stability of the values of the calibrated parameters over time. In fact, for each calibrated parameter we observe similar average value, minimum value, maximum value and standard division. The only exception is the parameter α for non-investment grade companies ((BB+)-(CCC)), where we observe that the average value of α is 0.071 in 2019 while it jumps to 0.017 in 2018. However, this difference is due to a single company with credit spreads of around 1500 basis points for short maturities (an outlier), that is a company that data indicate in strong financial distress. The details of these calibrations are available in Appendix C, see Table 8, where the estimated parameters are available for a selection of companies.

Table 5.

Statistics of the calibrated values and of the mean absolute percentage error (goodness of fit) for the credit risk model here considered

(AAA) – (A-) (BBB+) – (BBB-) (BB+) – (CCC)
2020 2019 2018 2020 2019 2018 2020 2019 2018
x0xL Average 3.224 3.225 3.428 2.999 3.009 3.180 2.583 2.560 2.904
Min 2.392 1.842 1.813 1.612 1.600 1.667 1.015 1.014 1.511
Max 4.716 4.465 4.999 4.977 4.327 4.518 4.936 3.126 3.972
SD 0.588 0.604 0.738 0.558 0.513 0.638 0.831 0.503 0.651
α Average 0.054 0.052 0.048 0.037 0.035 0.040 0.084 0.071 0.017
Min 0.022 0.007 0.018 0.009 0.004 -0.032 -0.030 -0.082 -0.031
Max 0.121 0.121 0.121 0.188 0.087 0.094 1.304 1.286 0.071
SD 0.020 0.020 0.019 0.023 0.016 0.020 0.315 0.315 0.030
σx Average 0.237 0.240 0.230 0.236 0.246 0.239 0.244 0.249 0.253
Min 0.177 0.125 0.121 0.101 0.100 0.103 0.114 0.111 0.102
Max 0.300 0.300 0.298 0.300 0.300 0.297 0.300 0.291 0.300
SD 0.032 0.036 0.036 0.030 0.035 0.042 0.047 0.049 0.063
a Average 0.010 0.009 0.006 0.009 0.010 0.008 0.005 0.008 0.009
Min -0.013 0.004 0.001 -0.009 0.004 0.001 -0.020 -0.020 0.000
Max 0.010 0.010 0.010 0.010 0.010 0.010 0.010 0.010 0.010
SD 0.003 0.001 0.003 0.003 0.001 0.003 0.010 0.008 0.003
b Average 1.506 2.059 1.407 1.277 1.487 1.552 -3.434 -2.731 -1.324
Min -2.804 0.098 0.257 -3.881 -6.739 -3.552 -19.946 -32.061 -51.891
Max 1.860 2.618 2.456 1.822 2.641 2.615 1.638 2.261 2.473
SD 0.672 0.539 0.659 1.075 1.801 0.922 7.351 8.648 13.053
λ Average 0.002 0.002 0.001 0.003 0.004 0.002 0.023 0.018 0.014
Min 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.000
Max 0.010 0.010 0.009 0.022 0.035 0.023 0.100 0.129 0.200
SD 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.003 0.007 0.003 0.033 0.032 0.048
MAPE% Average 8.520 4.795 3.862 8.058 5.071 4.875 5.700 5.769 5.406
Min 2.253 1.698 1.319 0.305 1.647 1.870 1.863 1.244 2.117
Max 19.234 9.673 14.753 15.765 11.842 19.870 10.188 9.232 8.565
SD 2.507 1.771 2.374 2.920 1.879 3.220 2.393 2.254 1.818

For each one of the 142 European companies listed in Appendix C, the parameters are calibrated by employing CDS spreads with maturities 6 months and 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 7, 10, 20 and 30 years. The CDS spreads used for the calibrations are quoted on February 3, 2020, on February 1, 2019, and on February 1, 2018. Companies are organized in three groups according to their S&P rating. The first group is made of 57 companies characterized by medium and high investment grade, that is credit rating greater than or equal to A-. The second group is made of 68 companies characterized by low investment grade, that is credit rating in the range BBB+ and BBB-. The third group is made of 17 companies characterized by speculative (no investment) grade, that is credit rating lower than BBB-. The statistics of the calibrations are available for each one of these three groups

Table 8.

Calibration of the credit risk model here proposed (formula ΠV) for the years 2018, 2019, and 2020, for a selected group of companies

Rating Company Model x0xL α σx a b MAPE %
AA Allianz SE 2020 3.506 0.064 0.247 0.010 1.665 9.18%
2019 3.500 0.069 0.245 0.010 2.535 3.99%
2018 2.980 0.032 0.185 0.005 1.295 5.46%
AA- Shell PLC 2020 2.940 0.041 0.219 0.010 1.775 11.22%
2019 3.396 0.027 0.229 0.008 2.027 2.79%
2018 3.506 0.031 0.234 0.003 0.671 4.05%
A+ BNP Paribas SA 2020 4.406 0.086 0.300 0.010 1.634 10.75%
2019 3.857 0.068 0.297 0.010 2.068 7.41%
2018 3.112 0.038 0.200 0.006 1.467 1.80%
A Banco Santander SA 2020 2.743 0.052 0.214 0.010 1.660 6.70%
2019 2.793 0.038 0.228 0.010 2.135 6.58%
2018 3.438 0.055 0.229 0.009 2.129 1.62%
A- Daimler AG 2020 2.600 0.023 0.210 0.010 1.443 6.65%
2019 2.500 0.031 0.216 0.010 2.049 6.23%
2018 3.083 0.041 0.217 0.009 2.429 6.10%
BBB+ Deutsche Telekom AG 2020 3.860 0.074 0.292 0.010 1.683 7.59%
2019 4.108 0.072 0.297 0.010 2.423 3.73%
2018 4.518 0.067 0.285 0.008 2.004 9.85%
BBB Banco Sabadell SA 2020 2.927 0.042 0.262 0.010 1.345 9.38%
2019 3.241 0.039 0.288 0.010 0.662 4.99%
2018 3.216 0.052 0.254 0.010 2.039 5.80%
BBB- Edison SpA 2020 2.599 0.042 0.216 0.010 1.573 4.60%
2019 2.466 0.041 0.209 0.010 2.238 3.13%
2018 3.449 0.064 0.289 0.010 2.236 5.13%
BB+ Leonardo SpA 2020 2.712 0.020 0.237 0.010 1.601 7.54%
2019 2.729 0.013 0.254 0.010 1.988 6.65%
2018 2.878 0.032 0.259 0.010 2.301 4.73%
B Selecta BV 2020 2.444 -0.006 0.266 0.010 0.383 4.85%
2019 2.595 -0.026 0.273 0.010 0.739 5.51%
2018 2.491 -0.026 0.265 0.010 0.410 5.06%

The calibration is performed by fitting the curve of CDS spreads using formula (21). Maturities: 6 months and 1, 2, 3, 5, 7, 10, 20 and 30 years. The CDS spreads used are quoted on February 3, 2020, on February 1, 2019, and on February 1, 2018. The CDSs employed have the following features. Restructuring clause: XR14. Seniority: Senior unsecured. The rating is by S&P. Thomson Reuters Eikon is our data provider. The calibrated values for all the other companies considered in the analysis are not reported for brevity, and are available upon request

The statistics of the calibrations available in Table 5 also provide interesting insights about the financial situations of companies with different credit rating. Considering the parameter x0xL, its value increases with the company’s credit rating. This is consistent with the fact that the credit quality of a company with a high credit rating should be higher than the one of a company with a low credit rating. The volatility of the signaling variable increases reducing the credit rating of the firm. This indicates that the creditworthiness (or credit quality) of companies with a low credit rating is more sensitive to random shocks (more subject to fluctuations).6 At the same time, the hazard rate increases on average more than ten times moving from companies with high credit rating, that is (AAA)-(A-), to companies with low credit rating, that is (BB+)-(CCC). This indicates that the probability of an unexpected default is higher for firms with a low credit rating. Moreover, we observe that the value of the parameter b is on average positive for companies with credit rating higher than or equal to BBB-. Therefore these companies are characterized by a positive duration gap. On the contrary, companies with a credit rating lower than BBB- are characterized by a negative value of b. Therefore these companies are characterized by a negative duration gap.

The negative duration gap for companies with low credit ratings indicates that these companies are more financially exposed than companies with high credit ratings. Moreover, for a company with positive (negative) duration gap the value of the activities increases more (less) than the values of the liabilities when the interest rate decreases. Thus, a reduction in risk-free interest rates makes low-credit-rated companies even more fragile, while high-credit-rated companies benefit from the reduction. As suggested by the hazard rate of the credit risk models considered in this work.7

Finally, focusing on two companies, that is Allianz Se and Dailmer AG, the credit risk model is calibrated every trading day in the period from January 1, 2018 to January 29, 2021. For each trading day, the calibration procedure employed is the one described at the beginning of this section. The results of the calibrations are shown in Figs. 5 and 6 and indicate how the valuation framework proposed captures the impact of special events such as the COVID-19 pandemic. Specifically, the parameters of the credit-quality signaling variable remain relatively stable over time. On the contrary, the intensity of default increases substantially in conjunction with COVID-19 pandemic. This allows to replicate the inflated CDS spreads that are observed in the period from March to April, 2020. In these two months the 5-year CDS spreads almost quadruple. The model therefore captures that the increase in CDS spreads is not due to firm-specific components but is due to macroeconomic events or endogenous shocks, specifically the COVID-19 pandemic.

Fig. 5.

Fig. 5

Rolling window calibrations for the CDS pricing formula (21) using daily observations of the CDS spreads written on debt issued by Allianz SE. Time window from 1-1-2018 to 29-1-2021. Panel (a), empirical 5-year CDS spreads (blue line) and theoretical 5-year CDS spreads (black and dashed line). Panel (b), calibrated values of the intensity of default λ. Panel (c), calibrated values of the ration between signaling variable and default barrier x0xL. Panel (d), calibrated values of the drift parameter of the signaling variable α. Panel (e), calibrated values of the short-term volatility of the signaling variable σx

Fig. 6.

Fig. 6

Rolling window calibrations for the CDS pricing formula (21) using daily observations of the CDS spreads written on debt issued by Dailmer AG. Time window from 1-1-2018 to 29-1-2021. a empirical 5-year CDS spreads (blue line) and theoretical 5-year CDS spreads (black and dashed line). b calibrated values of the intensity of default λ. c calibrated values of the ration between signaling variable and default barrier x0xL. d calibrated values of the drift parameter of the signaling variable α. e calibrated values of the short-term volatility of the signaling variable σx

Conclusions

In this work, a revised version of the credit risk model proposed in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) is considered. Specifically, the short-term interest rate is assumed to follow a Vasicek process instead of a CIR process. This allows us to account for negative interest rates, which are empirically observed in the last decade. Then, a formula for pricing CDS spreads is derived, which requires a hundred times less CPU time than the CDS pricing formula for the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003). In addition, an empirical analysis reveals that these two pricing formulas ensure the same goodness of fit. Therefore, the credit risk model proposed represents a valid alternative that may be of interest for practitioners. The validity of the model is also corroborated by the values of the parameters which, calibrated using the term structures of CDS spreads for 142 European companies, show large stability over time. Further applications of the model could focus on the study of the potential transmission of credit risk across sovereign, bank, and non-bank institutions (see e.g. Gross and Siklos 2020), or in the modeling of quanto CDS spreads (i.e. differences in CDS premia in different currency denominations, see e.g. Della Corte et al. 2018). We leave these streams of research to further works.

Acknowledgements

Davide Radi, Gabriele Torri and Hana Dvořáčková acknowledge the support of the Czech Science Foundation (GACR) under project 20-25660Y and VŠB-TU Ostrava under the SGS project SP2021/15.

Appendix A

Assuming that the risk-free rate follows a CIR process instead of a Vasicek process, the valuation framework in Sect. 2 becomes the hybrid credit risk model proposed in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003).

Specifically, Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) assumes that the risk-free rate follows process (1) where σrt,rt=σrrt. In this case, the risk-neutral price at the current time t0 of a default-free pure discount bond with maturity T is given by (see again Cox et al. 1985):

PCIRrt0,t0;T=eCt0;T+Dt0;Trt0 24

where

Ct0;T=2kμσr2ln2φek+φT-t022φ+k+φeφT-t0-1Dt0;T=-2eφT-t0-12φ+k+φeφT-t0-1 25

and φ=k2+2σr2.

Considering the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003), the formula for the probability to survive as well as the formula for the current price of a survival security are derived in the following Proposition (proof in Appendix B).

Proposition 5

Assuming the valuation framework in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003), we have that the probability to survive up to time T is given by

Qtd>T=fxt0,t0;TgCIRrt0,t0;T 26

where f is defined in (6), while

gCIRrt0,t0;T=eE5t0;T+E6t0;Trt0 27

where

E5t0;T=-aT-t0+2kμσr2ln2γek+γT-t022γ+k+γeγT-t0-1E6t0;T=-2beγT-t0-12γ+k+γeγT-t0-1 28

and γ=k2+2bσr2. The current price of a survival security with unitary face value and maturity T is given by

SCIRrt0,xt0,t0;T=fxt0,t0;Tg~CIRrt0,t0;T 29

where g~CIR is obtained by gCIR substituting b with b+1.

The current price of a survival security in Proposition 5 is the discounted value of the probability to survive when the short-term interest rate follows a CIR process. The formula for the current price of a survival security is available in closed form as shown in Proposition 5. Conversely, the forward price of a survival security does not admit a closed-form solution when the credit risk model in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) is employed.

Consider the forward measure QT to compute the forward price of a survival security, see, e.g., Madan and Unal (2000). We recap that QT is the unique equivalent martingale measure under which the values of traded assets discounted by the price of the default-free bond, in this case PCIRrt0,t0;T, are martingales.

The change of measure density process from Q to QT is given by the Radon-Nikodym derivative which is equal to the price of a risk-free bond with maturity T, see, e.g., Brigo and Mercurio (2007) and Madan and Unal (2000). Then, applying Girsanov’s theorem, the QT dynamics for x and r are given by

dxt=αxtdt+σxdWxtdrt=μk-rt-σx2Dt;Trtdt+σrdW~rt 30

where Wxt and W~rt are Wiener processes under QT while Dt;T is defined in (25). Since by assumption the signaling variable is uncorrelated to the short-term interest rate, its dynamics does not change when we move from the martingale measure Q to the forward measure QT, i.e. QTτx>T=Qτx>T.

Proposition 6

Assuming the valuation framework in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003), the forward price of a survival security with unitary face value and maturity T is given by

FCIRxt0,rt0,t0;T=QTtd>T=fxt0,t0;ThCIRrt0,t0;T 31

where f is defined in (6), while

hCIRrt0,t0;T=eE7t0;T+E8t0;Trt0 32

with E7 and E8 that solve the following system of two ordinary differential equations

E8,t=kE8+b-σr22E82-σr2Dt,TE8E7,t=-kμE8+a 33

subject to final conditions E7T,T=E8T,T=0. D·;· is defined as in (25).

Note that in order to compute the forward-price of a survival security, system (33) needs to be approximated numerically.

Appendix B

Proof of Proposition 1

Employing the results in (5)–(8), to derive the probability to survive Qtd>T we only need to compute EQ1τr>T. By standard results on Cox processes, we have that

gVrt,t;T=EQ1τr>T=EQe-tTλrsds 34

where λr=a+br is the intensity of default. Since by assumption r follows (under martingale measure Q) the Vasicek process (1), by Feynman-Kac formula, see, e.g., Friedman (1975) and Krylov (1980), we know that the function g satisfies the following partial differential problem:

-gV,t-kμ-rgV,r-σr22gV,rr+λrgV=0 35

subject to

gVrT,T;T=1 36

Guessing a solution of the form

gVrt,t;T=eE1t;T+E2t;Trt 37

we obtain

-E1,t-E2,tr-kμ-rE2-σr22E22+a+br=0 38

Then, by separation of variables we have the following system of two ordinary differential equations8

E2,t=kE2+bE1,t=-kμE2-σr22E22+a 39

from which, imposing the condition E2T;T=0, we obtain

E2t;T=be-kT-t-1k 40

It follows that

E1t;T=0t-kμE2-σr22E22+ads+C0=-μbe-kT-t-e-kTk+μbt-b2σr24k3e-2kTe2kt-1-b2σr22k2t+2σr2b22k3e-kT-t-e-kT+at+C0 41

Imposing E1T;T=0, we obtain

E1t;T=bσr22k2-μE1t;T+bT-t-σr24kE12t;T-aT-t 42

By definition, the price of a survival security with unitary face value is given by

EQ1td>Te-tTrsds 43

Since x and r are independent, (43) can be rewritten as

EQ1τx>TEQ1τr>Te-tTrsds 44

where EQ1τx>T is defined as in (6)–(8), while by standard results on Cox processes, we have that

EQ1τr>Te-tTrsds=EQe-tTλrs+rsds 45

Therefore, this expected value is equal to g~V, which is obtained by gV substituting b with b+1. This completes the proof.

Proof of Proposition 2

Note that QTtd>T=EQT1τx>TEQT1τr>T and EQT1τx>T=EQ1τx>T which is equal to f as shown in (6)–(8). Therefore, we need only to compute EQT1τr>T. By standard results on Cox processes, we have that

hVrt,t;T=EQT1τr>T=EQTe-tTλrsds 46

where λr=a+br. Since r follows process (30) under forward measure QT, by Feynman-Kac formula, see, e.g., Friedman (1975) and Krylov (1980), we know that the function hV satisfies the following partial differential problem:

-hV,t-kμ-r-σr2Bt,ThV,r-σr22hV,rr+λrhV=0 47

subject to

hVrT,T;T=1 48

where Bt,T is defined as in (3). Guessing a solution of the form

hVrt,t;T=eE3t,T+E4t,Trt 49

we have that

-E3,t+E4,tr-kμ-r-σr2Bt,TE4-σr22E42+λr=0 50

By separation of variables, we obtain

E4,t=kE4+bE3,t=-kμ-σr2Bt,TE4-σr22E42+a 51

Therefore, E4t;T=bBt;T and

E3t;T=Tt-kμE4s;T+σr2Bs,TE4s;Tds+Tt-σr22E42s;T+ads 52

Evaluating the integral we obtain E3t;T as in (16). This completes the proof.

Proof of Proposition 3

Consider the forward measure QT. Then the forward price of the protection leg is given by

EQT1-δ1T>td>t0=1-δEQT1-1τx>T1τr>T=1-δ1-EQT1τx>TEQT1τr>T 53

where EQT1τx>TEQT1τr>T is by definition the probability to survive under the forward measure (or forward price of a survival security). Since r follows process (30) under forward measure QT, the formula for the forward price of a survival security is FVx,r,t;T defined as in (14), see Proposition 2. Therefore, the current price Φ of the protection leg is given by:

Φx,r,t;T=PVr,t;T1-FVx,r,t;T1-δ 54

where PVr,t;T is the current price of a default-free pure discount bond defined as in (2). Concerning the premium leg, by Fubini’s theorem we have that

EQt0T1τx>zτr>ze-t0zrsdsdz=t0TEQ1τx>zτr>ze-t0zrsdsdz 55

where EQ1τx>zτr>ze-t0zrsds is, by definition, the current price of a survival security with unitary face value. Since by assumption r follows (under martingale measure Q) the Vasicek process (1), the formula for the current price of a survival security is given in (12), see Proposition 1. This completes the proof of the Proposition.

Proof of Proposition 5

Employing the results in (5)–(8), we need only to compute EQ1τr>T in order to derive the probability to survive Qtd>T. By standard results on Cox processes, we have that

gCIRrt,t;T=EQ1τr>T=EQe-tTλrsds 56

where λr=a+br is the intensity of default. Since by assumption r follows (under martingale measure Q) the CIR process as indicated in Appendix A, by Feynman-Kac formula, see, e.g., Friedman (1975) and Krylov (1980), we know that the function gCIR satisfies the following partial differential problem:

-gCIR,t-kμ-rgCIR,r-σr22rgCIR,rr+λrgCIR=0 57

subject to

gCIRrT,T;T=1 58

Guessing a solution of the form

gCIRr,t;T=eE5t;T+E6t;Trt 59

we obtain

-E5,t-E6,tr-kμ-rE6-σr22rE62+a+br=0 60

Then, by separation of variables we have the following system of two ordinary differential equations:

E5,t=a-kμE6E6,t=b+kE6-σr22E62 61

where the second one is a Riccati equation, subject to the conditions E5T;T=E6T;T=0. Following (Polyanin and Zaitsev 2003, sec.1.2.1), set

σr22E6t;T=utt;Tut;T 62

from which we have that

E6,t=2σr2uttu-ut2u2=b+k2σr2utu-2σr2ut2u2 63

Therefore, u satisfies the following second-order ordinary differential equation

utt-kut-bσr22u=0 64

Since γ2=k2+2bσr2>0, its solution, see (Polyanin and Zaitsev 2003, sec. 2.1.2-2), is given by

u=C1e12k+γt+C2e12k-γt 65

and its derivative is

ut=C112k+γe12k+γt+C212k-γe12k-γt 66

By imposing ut=0 in t=T, which allow us to have the final condition E6T;T=0 satisfied, we obtain

C2=-C1k+γk-γeγT 67

Therefore,

u=C1e12k+γt-C1k+γk-γeγTe+12k-γt 68

and

E6t;T=2σr2C112k+γe12k+γt-C1eγT12k+γe12k-γtC1e12k+γt-C1k+γk-γeγTe+12k-γt=-2beγT-t-12γ+k+γeγT-t-1 69

Then,

E5t;T=Ttads-kμTtE6s;Tds=-aT-t+2kμσr2ln2γek+γ2T-t2γ+k+γeγT-t-1 70

By definition, the price of a survival security with unitary face value is given by

EQ1td>Te-tTrsds 71

Since x and r are independent, (71) can be rewritten as

EQ1τx>TEQ1τr>Te-tTλrsds 72

where EQ1τx>T is defined as in (6)–(8), while by standard results on Cox processes, we have that

EQ1τr>Te-tTrsds=EQe-tTλrs+rsds 73

Therefore, this expected value is equal to g~CIR, which is obtained by gCIR substituting b with b+1. This completes the proof.

Proof of Proposition 6

Note that QTtd>T=EQT1τx>TEQT1τr>T and EQT1τx>T=EQ1τx>T which is equal to f as shown in (6)–(8). Therefore, we need only to compute EQT1τr>T. By standard results on Cox processes, we have that

hCIRrt,t;T=EQT1τr>T=EQTe-tTλrsds 74

where λr=a+br is the intensity of default. Since r follows process (30) under forward measure QT, by Feynman-Kac formula, see, e.g., Friedman (1975) and Krylov (1980), we know that the function hCIR satisfies the following partial differential problem:

-hCIR,t-kμ-r-σr2Dt,TrhCIR,r-σr22rhCIR,rr+λrhCIR=0 75

subject to

hCIRrT,T;T=1 76

where Dt,T=-21-exp-φT-t02φ+k-φexp-φT-t0 is as in (25). Guessing a solution of the form

hCIRrt,t;T=eE7t,T+E8t,Trt 77

we obtain

-E7,t+E8,tr-kμ-r-σr2Dt,TrE8-σr22rE82+λr=0 78

By separation of variables, we have the system of ordinary differential equations in (33) subject to final condition E7T,T=E8T,T=0. This completes the proof.

Appendix C

Table 6 reports the descriptive statistics for the CDS spreads considered. As expected, spreads tend to be higher for companies with worse credit rating, and on average were the highest in 2019. Considering the spread curve, spreads are typically higher for longer maturities indicating a positively sloped curve. The results of the calibrations for a selection of companies is available in Tables 7 and 8. Specifically, Table 7 shows the results of the calibrations (using quotations on February 3, 2020) for CDS pricing formulas (21) and (22), while Table 8 shows the calibrations for CDS pricing formula (21) in three different days, that is on February 3, 2020, on February 1, 2019, and on February 1, 2018. Finally, Table 9 reports the list of the 142 companies considered in the study.

Table 6.

Statistics of the CDS spreads employed in the empirical analyzes here conducted

(AAA) – (A-) (BBB+) – (BBB-) (BB+) – (CCC)
2020 2019 2018 2020 2019 2018 2020 2019 2018
1 yr spread (%) average 0.1042 0.1405 0.0932 0.1789 0.2841 0.1420 2.2272 1.3618 0.8167
min 0.0292 0.0409 0.0199 0.0338 0.0489 0.0122 0.0858 0.0508 0.0505
max 0.6314 0.5811 0.5504 1.3142 1.9967 1.3013 12.7028 10.9834 9.8224
SD 0.1012 0.0956 0.0868 0.2041 0.3747 0.1754 3.6774 2.6002 2.3275
5 yr spread (%) average 0.3301 0.4866 0.3188 0.6419 0.9448 0.5697 3.5204 3.1071 1.7693
min 0.1364 0.1509 0.1326 0.1858 0.2837 0.2455 0.6927 0.8034 0.5895
max 1.0003 1.0739 0.9008 1.9744 2.7815 1.7162 13.0551 7.6227 6.4411
SD 0.1549 0.2005 0.1362 0.3509 0.5634 0.2653 3.3901 2.0977 1.5437
10 yr spread (%) average 0.5897 0.7810 0.5828 1.0535 1.3542 0.9601 3.9485 3.7560 2.3981
min 0.3066 0.3304 0.2879 0.4349 0.5766 0.5143 1.0073 0.9728 1.0096
max 1.1963 1.5169 1.0982 2.4417 3.0960 3.0419 11.6705 8.4380 5.7303
SD 0.2043 0.2591 0.1742 0.4245 0.5857 0.3757 2.9486 2.0516 1.4841
Curve slope (%) average 0.0539 0.0712 0.0544 0.0972 0.1189 0.0909 0.1913 0.2660 0.1757
min 0.0087 0.0251 0.0250 0.0025 0.0033 0.0037 − 0.4936 − 0.5850 − 0.4547
max 0.1075 0.1314 0.0934 0.2315 0.2758 0.2975 0.5108 0.8054 0.4962
SD 0.0196 0.0241 0.0160 0.0425 0.0486 0.0397 0.2415 0.2893 0.2005
Num. of companies 57 68 17

The CDS spreads used for the calibrations are quoted on February 3, 2020, on February 1, 2019, and on February 1, 2018. Companies are organized in three groups according to their S&P rating. The first group is made of 57 companies characterized by medium and high investment grade, that is credit rating greater than or equal to A-. The second group is made of 68 companies characterized by low investment grade, that is credit rating in the range BBB+ and BBB-. The third group is made of 17 companies characterized by speculative (no investment) grade, that is credit rating lower than BBB-. The descriptive statistics are available for each one of these three groups. Curve slope is computed as: 10yrs spread-1yr spread10-1

Table 9.

List of the European companies to which the CDS spreads used for the calibrations refer to and their S&P’s credit rating

Company S&P’s rating Company S&P’s rating Company S&P’s rating
Allianz SE AA Gecina SA A- Ahold Delhaize NV BBB
Deutsche Bahn AG AA ING Groep NV A- Lafarge SA BBB
Sanofi SA AA Kering SA A- LANXESS AG BBB
apoBank eG AA- Klepierre SA A- Mediobanca SpA BBB
DZ BANK AG AA- Koninklijke DSM NV A- Naturgy SA BBB
Hannover RE AA- Schneider Electric SE A- NXP BV BBB
Munich Re AA- Sodexo SA A- PostNL NV BBB
Shell PLC AA- Thales SA A- Publicis Groupe SA BBB
Scor SE AA- Vinci SA A- Repsol SA BBB
Airbus SE A+ Akzo Nobel NV BBB+ Telefonica Europe BV BBB
BMW AG A+ AIB PLC BBB+ Telefonica SA BBB
BNP Fortis SA A+ BNL SpA BBB+ UniCredit SpA BBB
BNP Paribas SA A+ Bankinter SA BBB+ Veolia SA BBB
Rabobank NV A+ Bertelsmann SE BBB+ Vivendi SA BBB
Credit Agricole CIB A+ Capgemini SE BBB+ Wendel SE BBB
Credit Agricole SA A+ Continental AG BBB+ Abertis SA BBB-
Credit Lyonnais SA A+ Danone SA BBB+ Accor SA BBB-
ING Bank NV A+ Deutsche Bank AG BBB+ Auchan SA BBB-
KBC Bank NV A+ Deutsche Telekom AG BBB+ Edison SpA BBB-
LVMH SE A+ Endesa SA BBB+ EDP SA BBB-
Siemens AG A+ Enel SpA BBB+ EDP Finance BV BBB-
Total SA A+ Heineken NV BBB+ HeidelbergCement AG BBB-
Unilever NV A+ Iberdrola SA BBB+ OTE SA BBB-
AXA SA A Philips NV BBB+ Peugeot SA BBB-
Banco Santander SA A NN Group NV BBB+ Renault SA BBB-
BFCM SA A Orange SA BBB+ Schaeffler AG BBB-
BASF SE A Pernod Ricard SA BBB+ Suedzucker AG BBB-
Erste Bank AG A RBI AG BBB+ UBI Banca SpA BBB-
Henkel AG A Telekom Austria AG BBB+ Valeo SA BBB-
Helaba A TF1 SA BBB+ Leonardo SpA BB+
Linde AG A Terna SpA BBB+ Smurfit Kappa PLC BB+
Merck KGaA A HVB AG BBB+ TIM SpA BB+
Societe Generale SA A Volkswagen AG BBB+ Millennium BCP SA BB
Wfd Unibail-Rodamco SE A VWFS AG BBB+ INEOS Group SA BB
Aegon NV A- Wolters Kluwer NV BBB+ Nielsen Co BV BB
Air Liquide SA A- Banco Sabadell SA BBB Rexel SA BB
AB InBev NV A- Bankia SA BBB Atlantia SpA BB-
ASF SA A- Bayer AG BBB EUCAR SA BB-
BBVA SA A- Carrefour SA BBB Thyssenkrupp AG BB-
Bank of Ireland PLC A- Saint-Gobain SA BBB TUI AG BB-
Bouygues SA A- Lufthansa AG BBB UPC Holding BV BB-
Commerzbank AG A- DCL SA BBB CMA CGM SA B+
Michelin SCA A- DVB Bank SE BBB Alpha Bank SA B
Daimler AG A- E.ON SE BBB Groupe Casino SA B
EDF SA A- Fresenius SE BBB Novafives SAS B
EnBW AG A- Hochtief AG BBB Selecta BV B
Engie SA A- Infineon Technologies AG BBB
Eni SpA A- Intesa Sanpaolo SpA BBB

Funding

Open access funding provided by Università di Pisa within the CRUI-CARE Agreement.

Declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Footnotes

1

This allows us to capture the so-called leverage effect, that is value and volatility of equity are negatively correlated. However, Das and Sundaram (2007) conclude that the leverage effect has a limited impact on the term structure of default swap spreads and a geometric Brownian motion can be used to approximate firm’s equity value.

2

The CIR process was preferred to the Vasicek process till the 2007-2008 financial crisis. Afterwards, the observation of negative interest rates brought Vasicek model back into vogue. Indeed, differently from the CIR model, the Vasicek model allows to have negative interest rates with positive probability.

3

It can be considered a proxy of the firm’s equity value.

4

Only CDSs with maturities lower than or equal to 30 years are considered in the empirical analysis that follows and in general CDSs with maturities higher than 30 years are not traded. Concerning the order of approximation, the numerical test conducted, which is not reported here for the sake of space, indicates a computational error lower than 10-4. Since a CDS spread is measured in basis points, computing a CDS pricing formula with a level of precision of 10-4 is enough for the purpose of our application.

5

For the sake of comparison, the CDS pricing formula derived in Ballestra et al. (2020) for the valuation framework in Cathcart and El-Jahel (2003) is rewritten in (22) in terms of the price of a default-free bond, the current price of survival security and the forward price of a survival security, see appendix A.

6

This is consistent with the so-called leverage effect, according to which the volatility of a firm’s equity value is inversely related to the value of the equity itself, see, e.g., Das and Sundaram (2007). A property that is also inherent in the structural models, such as the ones in Merton (1974) and in Longstaff and Schwartz (1995).

7

The positive relationship between credit spread and risk-free rate observed for high rated (investment grade) companies is apparently inconsistent with the predictions of structural models, see, e.g., Merton (1974) and Longstaff and Schwartz (1995). However, this difference relay on the fact that structural models consider the direct effect, i.e. these models are based on the assumption that the growth rate of the value of the assets of a firm is proportional to the risk-free rate. On the contrary, the current modeling framework is based on the assumption that the credit quality signaling variable is not correlated to the risk-free interest rate. Therefore, only the indirect effect of the interest rate is considered, i.e. its role as a discount factor, which justifies a positive relationship between credit spreads and risk-free rates. Our results are consistent with the ones in Ballestra et al. (2020) and with the empirical evidence of a positive relationship between credit spreads and risk-free rates over the long-run documented in Morris et al. (1998).

8

The reader who is not familiar with dynamical systems is referred to Teschl (2012) and Bischi et al. (2016).

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

References

  1. Altman EI, Kishore VM. Almost everything you wanted to know about recoveries on defaulted bonds. Financ. Anal. J. 1996;52(6):57–64. doi: 10.2469/faj.v52.n6.2040. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  2. Ballestra, L.V., Pacelli, G., Radi, D.: A note on Fergusson and Platen, ”Application of maximum likelihood estimation to stochastic short rate models”. Annals of Financial Economics 11(4), 1650,018 (2016)
  3. Ballestra LV, Pacelli G, Radi D. Computing the survival probability in the Madan-Unal credit risk model: Application to the CDS market. Quant. Finance. 2017;17(2):299–313. doi: 10.1080/14697688.2016.1189590. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  4. Ballestra LV, Pacelli G, Radi D. Modeling CDS spreads: a comparison of some hybrid approaches. J. Empir. Financ. 2020;57:107–124. doi: 10.1016/j.jempfin.2020.03.001. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  5. Bischi, G., Lamantia, F., Radi, D.: Qualitative Theory of Dynamical Systems, Tools and Applications for Economic Modelling, Springer Proceedings in Complexity, chap Qualitative Methods in Continuous and Discrete Dynamical Systems, pp. 1–159. (2016). 10.1007/978-3-319-33276-5_1
  6. Black F, Cox JC. Valuing corporate securities: some effects of bond indenture provisions. J. Financ. 1976;31(2):351–367. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1976.tb01891.x. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  7. Brigo D, Mercurio F. Interest Rate Models–Theory and Practice: With Smile, Inflation and Credit. 2. Berlin: Springer, Springer Finance; 2007. [Google Scholar]
  8. Cathcart L, El-Jahel L. Semi-analytical pricing of defaultable bonds in a signaling jump-default model. J. Comput. Finance. 2003;6(3):91–108. doi: 10.21314/JCF.2003.105. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  9. Cathcart L, El-Jahel L. Pricing defaultable bonds: a middle-way approach between structural and reduced-form models. Quant. Finance. 2006;6(3):243–253. doi: 10.1080/14697680600670754. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  10. Cox J, Ingersoll JE, Jr, Ross S. A theory of the term structure of interest rates. Econ. J. Econ. Soc. 1985;53(2):385–408. [Google Scholar]
  11. Das SR, Sundaram RK. An integrated model for hybrid securities. Manage. Sci. 2007;53(9):1439–1451. doi: 10.1287/mnsc.1070.0702. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  12. Della Corte, P., Sarno, L., Schmeling, M., Wagner, C.: Exchange rates and sovereign risk. 2354935 (2018)
  13. Duffee GR. Estimating the price of default risk. Rev. Financ. Stud. 1999;12(1):197–226. doi: 10.1093/rfs/12.1.197. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  14. Duffie D, Lando D. Term structures of credit spreads with incomplete accounting information. Econ. J. Econo. Soc. 2001;69(3):633–664. [Google Scholar]
  15. Duffie D, Singleton KJ. Modeling term structures of defaultable bonds. Rev. Financ. Stud. 1999;12(4):687–720. doi: 10.1093/rfs/12.4.687. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  16. Feng R, Volkmer HW. Modeling credit value adjustment with downgrade-triggered termination clause using a ruin theoretic approach. Insur. Math. Econ. 2012;51(2):409–421. doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2012.06.007. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  17. Fergusson K, Platen E. Application of maximum likelihood estimation to stochastic short rate models. Ann. Financ. Econ. 2015;10(2):1550009. doi: 10.1142/S2010495215500098. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  18. Fontana C, Montes JMA. A unified approach to pricing and risk management of equity and credit risk. J. Comput. Appl. Math. 2014;259:350–361. doi: 10.1016/j.cam.2013.04.047. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  19. Franks JR, Torous WN. An empirical investigation of US firms in reorganization. J. Finance. 1989;44(3):747–769. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1989.tb04389.x. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  20. Friedman A. Stochastic Differential Equations and Applications. New York: Academic Press; 1975. [Google Scholar]
  21. Giesecke K. Default and information. J. Econ. Dyn. Control. 2006;30(11):2281–2303. doi: 10.1016/j.jedc.2005.07.003. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  22. Gross C, Siklos PL. Analyzing credit risk transmission to the nonfinancial sector in europe: A network approach. J. Appl. Economet. 2020;35(1):61–81. doi: 10.1002/jae.2726. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  23. Gündüz Y, Uhrig-Homburg M. Does modeling framework matter? A comparative study of structural and reduced-form models. Rev. Deriv. Res. 2014;17(1):39–78. doi: 10.1007/s11147-013-9090-8. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  24. Guo X, Jarrow RA, Lin H. Distressed debt prices and recovery rate estimation. Rev. Deriv. Res. 2008;11(3):171–204. doi: 10.1007/s11147-009-9029-2. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  25. Hao X, Li X, Shimizu Y. Finite-time survival probability and credit default swaps pricing under geometric Lévy markets. Insurance Math. Econ. 2013;53(1):14–23. doi: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2013.04.003. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  26. Jankowitsch R, Pullirsch R, Veža T. The delivery option in credit default swaps. J. Bank. Finance. 2008;32(7):1269–1285. doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2007.10.012. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  27. Jarrow RA, Turnbull SM. Pricing derivatives on financial securities subject to credit risk. J. Financ. 1995;50(1):53–85. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1995.tb05167.x. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  28. Jones EP, Mason SP, Rosenfeld E. Contingent claims analysis of corporate capital structures: An empirical investigation. J. Financ. 1984;39(3):611–625. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1984.tb03649.x. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  29. Krylov N. Controlled Diffusion Processes. New York: Springer; 1980. [Google Scholar]
  30. Lando D. On Cox processes and credit risky securities. Rev. Deriv. Res. 1998;2(2–3):99–120. [Google Scholar]
  31. Longstaff FA, Schwartz ES. A simple approach to valuing risky fixed and floating rate debt. J. Financ. 1995;50(3):789–819. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1995.tb04037.x. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  32. Madan DB. Modeling and monitoring risk acceptability in markets: The case of the credit default swap market. J. Bank. Finance. 2014;47:63–73. doi: 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.05.024. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  33. Madan DB, Schoutens W. Break on through to the single side. J. Credit Risk. 2008;4(3):3–20. doi: 10.21314/JCR.2008.076. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  34. Madan DB, Unal H. Pricing the risks of default. Rev. Deriv. Res. 1998;2(2–3):121–160. [Google Scholar]
  35. Madan DB, Unal H. A two-factor hazard rate model for pricing risky debt and the term structure of credit spreads. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 2000;35(1):43–65. doi: 10.2307/2676238. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  36. Merton RC. On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interest rates. J. Financ. 1974;29(2):449–470. [Google Scholar]
  37. Morris, C., Neal, R., Rolph, D.: Credit spreads and interest rates: a cointegration approach. Research Working Paper 98-08, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City (1998)
  38. Packer, F., Zhu, H.: Contractual terms and CDS pricing. (2005). BIS Quarterly Review Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1884901
  39. Polyanin, A.D., Zaitsev, V.F.: Exact Solutions for Ordinary Differential Equations. Chapman & Hall/CRC (2003)
  40. Schoutens W, Cariboni J. Lévy Processes in Credit Risk. New York: Wiley; 2009. [Google Scholar]
  41. Shreve SE. Stochastic Calculus for Finance II: Continuous-Time Models. Springer Finance: Springer; 2010. [Google Scholar]
  42. Teschl G. Ordinary Differential Equations and Dynamical Systems, Graduate Studies in Mathematics. New York: American Mathematical Society; 2012. [Google Scholar]
  43. Vasicek O. An equilibirum characterization of the term structure. J. Financ. Econ. 1977;5(2):177–188. doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(77)90016-2. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  44. Zhou C. The term structure of credit spreads with jump risk. J. Bank. Finance. 2001;25(11):2015–2040. doi: 10.1016/S0378-4266(00)00168-0. [DOI] [Google Scholar]

Articles from Decisions in Economics and Finance are provided here courtesy of Nature Publishing Group

RESOURCES