Skip to main content
Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences logoLink to Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences
. 2021 Oct 4;376(1838):20200297. doi: 10.1098/rstb.2020.0297

Networks of reliable reputations and cooperation: a review

Károly Takács 1,2,, Jörg Gross 3, Martina Testori 4, Srebrenka Letina 1,5, Adam R Kenny 6,7, Eleanor A Power 8, Rafael P M Wittek 9
PMCID: PMC8487750  PMID: 34601917

Abstract

Reputation has been shown to provide an informal solution to the problem of cooperation in human societies. After reviewing models that connect reputations and cooperation, we address how reputation results from information exchange embedded in a social network that changes endogenously itself. Theoretical studies highlight that network topologies have different effects on the extent of cooperation, since they can foster or hinder the flow of reputational information. Subsequently, we review models and empirical studies that intend to grasp the coevolution of reputations, cooperation and social networks. We identify open questions in the literature concerning how networks affect the accuracy of reputations, the honesty of shared information and the spread of reputational information. Certain network topologies may facilitate biased beliefs and intergroup competition or in-group identity formation that could lead to high cooperation within but conflicts between different subgroups of a network. Our review covers theoretical, experimental and field studies across various disciplines that target these questions and could explain how the dynamics of interactions and reputations help or prevent the establishment and sustainability of cooperation in small- and large-scale societies.

This article is part of the theme issue ‘The language of cooperation: reputation and honest signalling’.

Keywords: cooperation, social networks, reputation, indirect reciprocity, intergroup relations, relational multiplexity

1. Introduction

Despite its obvious benefits, cooperation necessarily entails individual sacrifices, and so poses a fundamental puzzle for evolutionary theory, already alluded to by Darwin [1;2, pp. 5–8]. Many breakthroughs in evolution, however, have been achieved through cooperation and the formation of cooperative alliances [3]. For example, the transition from single-celled to multicellular organisms required the restriction of individual cell growth, cellular differentiation and the management of cheating—cooperation between cells to create a functioning organism [46]. Here, we focus our attention on cooperation in humans, as our species is particularly skilled in resolving cooperation problems and regularly cooperate with non-kin strangers [7,8]. It has been a major scientific achievement to realize and empirically demonstrate that humans are capable of solving the problem of cooperation through reputation [914]. Reputation can be defined as (shared) information about the qualities and attributes of an individual that also includes cooperativeness [15,16]. Reputational information can be used to condition behaviour towards an interaction partner. Furthermore, it can determine access to partner choice and reproduction as well as to material and to immaterial resources (e.g. to power). The benefits of having a ‘good’ reputation can deter individuals from defection and thereby foster the evolution of cooperation [1719].

These processes do not take place in a social vacuum. Human interactions are complex, as they are embedded in social network structures. The local network ties that an individual has are important for solving the problem of cooperation for multiple reasons. First, the local network structure provides the context of social interdependencies, and large-scale cooperation is often scaled up from the successful establishment of local cooperation. Second, network ties provide the constraints of monitoring and controlling behaviour. Third, they are also the channels of communication. Communication is a device for coordination, but also for influence and persuasion towards doing the right thing for the larger group. The advanced communication capacities and social skills of humans allow us to disseminate third-party evaluations through gossip [14,2022]. Gossip is the method through which one learns the reputations of others, and through which reputations are shared in the absence of direct experience and observation. These processes also sustain reputation-based cooperation in larger groups in which not every interaction can be monitored [2325].

In short, network ties impact cooperation through multiple mechanisms. They can help the establishment of reputations that are aligned with group-beneficiary action but could potentially also be used to control the flow of, or strategically manipulate, reputational information [26].

After a short introduction to the problem of cooperation, we review work on the foundational elements of reputation-based cooperation in humans. We start from the simplest models that link reputation and cooperation, and then address the impact of networks on cooperation, before finally discussing more complex models of their coevolution. We conclude that the existing theoretical work on reputation and cooperation has not fully accounted for the possible complex interplay that emerges when social networks dynamically change as a function of gossip and reputation (e.g. [27]). While such dynamics pose many challenges, we argue that progressing the field towards investigating the interactions of reputation, gossip and network topology might help to overcome the remaining puzzles of how networks can ensure reliable reputation systems assisting the evolution of cooperation. Such a programme also promises explanations for when and why gossip and reputation dynamics have adverse effects on cooperation, by fostering dishonesty, strategic manipulation attempts, or by giving rise to parochial, group-bounded cooperation.

2. The problem of cooperation

Cooperation is defined as a costly action to benefit another individual, where the benefit b is higher than the cost c (with b > c and c > 0) [7]. What follows is that mutual cooperation leads to higher social welfare than mutual defection. In other words, working together creates synergies that exceed what individuals alone are capable of. Yet, individuals are even better off by reaping the benefits of cooperation without paying the cost of cooperation themselves. This temptation to free-ride on the cooperation of others introduces a ‘puzzle’: How can cooperation emerge, given the risk of exploitation and, concomitantly, the temptation to exploit?

Prominent theories in biology explain cooperation based on kinship ([28,29], cf. [30]) and reciprocal interactions [3133]. While these theories apply to human cooperation as well, the remarkable extent of large-scale cooperation among non-kin observed in humans has shifted the attention to the role of reputation, communication, and social networks for sustaining cooperation.

3. Reputation as a mechanism for solving the problem of cooperation

Humans are able to observe the actions of others and exchange information. This allows the evolution of cooperation through mechanisms such as indirect reciprocity and reputation [12]. Communication and the ability to track reputation enable decision rules like ‘if someone told me that you cooperated with others in the past, I cooperate with you’. Cooperative decisions that are made conditional on transmitted information (i.e. ‘reputation’) also allow the extension of cooperation beyond dyadic relations. In a simple model, Nowak & Sigmund [11] showed that, if individuals base their decisions on the so-called image score of the interaction partner, simply operationalized as the number of times an individual helped others in the past, cooperators can avoid exploitation by identifying free-riders pre-emptively. Testing Nowak & Sigmund's model experimentally, Wedekind & Milinski [34] have shown that human participants are indeed sensitive to image scores and cooperate conditionally on whether the interaction partner has a good reputation (i.e. high image score).

Once good reputation pays off, individuals have an incentive to ‘invest’ in building it. Whether the expected benefits exceed the costs of investment depends on the size of the population, the reliability of the image score transmission, the number of future interactions and whether reputation provides a valid and reliable signal of cooperativeness in the first place [35]. The latter is open to exploitation as individuals may be able to increase their own reputation by buying ‘fake’ reputation (e.g. [36]). This means that reputation can be increased artificially without actually engaging in costly cooperation, enabling the exploitation of cooperators. Experimental results highlight how important the validity of reputation signals is and suggest that any reputation system has to mitigate the presence of adverse incentives to control and manipulate reputational information [37]. Recent studies have also shown that reputation scores can lose their ability to foster cooperation if they are assigned to groups rather than individuals or when cooperation takes place in groups rather than dyadic interactions [38,39].

Since the introduction of the ‘image score’ as a simplified concept of reputation, different rules on how to assign reputation based on past action have been proposed and analysed (see e.g. [4046]). Not all rules can sustain cooperation. From all consensual attributions, only eight norms (the so-called leading eight) that determine proper action and assignment of good reputation have been shown to maintain cooperation while being resistant to mutation and observation error [44,45]. The joint properties of the leading eight norms are that (i) they assign good reputation for cooperation by actors with good reputation against others with good reputation (maintenance of cooperation); (ii) they assign bad reputation for defection against individuals with good reputation (identification of defectors); (iii) they maintain good reputation for actors with good reputation after defection against individuals with bad reputation (justified punishment); and (iv) they assign good reputation for actors with bad reputation if they cooperated with individuals with good reputation (forgiveness) [44,45].

Reputation is an important mechanism for the emergence of cooperation not only because it might be the basis of conditional cooperation, but also because it could be the basis of whom to learn from [47]. When individuals with high reputation discount the behavioural strategies of individuals with low reputation, cooperation is further enhanced, especially if discounting is based on absolute rather than on relative reputation [47].

Most importantly, reputation can also be the basis of partner choice [25,4851]. Under ideal circumstances, reputational information allows predictions about the likely action of other agents in the population. Partner choice or ‘relational mobility’ allows cooperative agents to seek out partners that have a ‘good’ reputation and avoid agents with a ‘bad’ reputation. This creates competition for the attention of other cooperators in so-called biological markets in which agents compete to be selected as interaction partners [5256]. In theory, if reputation provides a valid and unambiguous signal of an agent's cooperativeness, cooperators have a competitive advantage over defectors, since they can exclusively interact with each other and gain from the mutual benefits of cooperation.

Reputation, however, is not necessarily available publicly or shared universally [5762]. While individuals may observe the actions of others, reputational information in humans is often also transmitted through gossip [6366]. Gossip allows people to sustain cooperative behaviours through the spread of negative reputation and the fear of retaliation [17], as well as through the creation of coalitions and the exercise of ostracism [16,22,25,67,68]. Yet, gossip can also be used strategically by sharing false information to damage the reputation of others, raising the question of how groups evaluate gossip and detect false accusations and strategic misinformation [6972]. In addition to strategic lies, gossip might entail a non-negligible degree of noise (that is, unintended errors). Gossip information can be wrongly communicated, impeding the correct transmission of reputational information and leading to mistakes in updating reputation of others [69,73]. Receivers may also wrongly interpret gossip information, likewise increasing the noise of reputational information [74,75]. Hess & Hagen [69] provided evidence that people evaluate the veracity of gossip information, for example, by assigning more credibility to gossip information coming from multiple, independent sources or taking into account the relationship between the gossiper and the gossip target, which can increase the reliability and validity of gossip and reduce strategic gossip lies and unintended errors. Such complexities are often not incorporated in formalized theoretical models, but play an important role in social groups, extend the function of reputation beyond simply identifying free-riders or cooperators, and introduce noise and strategic signalling, and psychological mechanisms to prevent the spread of false gossip.

4. Networks and cooperation

In large groups, people do not meet randomly, as assumed in some theoretical models for simplification. Human interactions are embedded in social networks that determine the likelihood with which two people meet, interact and exchange information. A logical implication is that the structure of a network could influence cooperation. Network topologies and features like how segmented, dense, close-knit or centralized a network is, might strongly facilitate or hinder the emergence of cooperation by constraining interactions or information transmission that might occur (table 1). In this section, we briefly review how networks can foster cooperation through mechanisms other than reputation.

Table 1.

Key network concepts relevant for cooperation.

concept definition/explanation visual representation
network segmentation the network can be partitioned into unconnected components; no influence on behaviour or on reputations is possible between the components graphic file with name rstb20200297f03.jpg
network clustering/modularity /segregation/assortativity of nodes/the small-world phenomenon human networks are characterized by dense and cohesive communities in which individuals show a large amount of similarity with each other (indicated by node colour). These cohesive clusters (modules) are loosely connected with each other through bridging ties (dotted lines), resulting in shorter network distances and a small world [76,77]. graphic file with name rstb20200297f04.jpg
influence and selection/coevolution of networks and cooperation the behavioural similarity of individuals in a community (cohesive subgraph) could be a result of social influence (assimilation, social learning) in informal relations or partner selection based on homophily [78,79] graphic file with name rstb20200297f05.jpg
brokerage/betweenness/centrality/power/social control individuals may be in a distinguished network position such that they connect otherwise unconnected others (brokers, red), most information flows through them (betweenness, yellow), can influence many others (centrality, purple), or can exploit the cooperation of others (isolates, peripheral actors, blue) graphic file with name rstb20200297f06.jpg
network multiplexity human networks are multiplex, and networks of interdependence, communication and influence are just partially overlapping graphic file with name rstb20200297f07.jpg
gossip a sender i communicating to a receiver j about a target k who is absent or unaware of the content [66] graphic file with name rstb20200297f08.jpg
structural constraints on the spread of reputations the presence of certain network ties (e.g. friendship between the receiver j and target k, or a 2-path friendship tie of j–lk) makes (negative) gossip about k by sender i to receiver j unlikely or forbidden graphic file with name rstb20200297f09.jpg
triadic closure/structural holes triadic closure (left) might be useful to cross-check the validity of reputational information received, while structural holes (right) enable the in-flow of information from independent sources [80] graphic file with name rstb20200297f10.jpg
consensual reputation/oppositional cultures reputational information about an individual may (top) or may not (top versus bottom) be consensual as different subgroups may hold contradicting views about someone's reputation graphic file with name rstb20200297f11.jpg

When the likelihood to meet and interact with people remains unchanged over time, the ability to distinguish partners and act according to their previous actions can enable cooperation in networks [8187]. A simple rule to foster cooperation in networks relates to the ratio between benefits b, costs c and individual degree d (d is the number of interaction partners that each agent has in the network). If b/c > d, the evolution of cooperation is theoretically possible without the need of reputation or strategic complexity [88].

People do not all occupy structurally identical positions and social networks often display skewed degree distributions [89]. Degree heterogeneity [90] and scale-free networks in particular have been shown to increase the chances of cooperation [81,84,9193], though they are also highly vulnerable to error and deletion of nodes [94]. Realistic small-world structures [95] were also found to provide better conditions for cooperation [96]. Systematic investigations of topologies confirmed the superiority of structures in which hubs are integrated in cohesive cliques while they are also linked elsewhere [97]. Structural advantages are due to the benefits of cooperation for hubs and bridging individuals, their larger impact on the behaviour of others, the presence of ties and correlated behaviour among hubs, and high local clustering in small-world networks [98100]. These results initiated the investigation of degree-based allocation policies that either decrease the required investments or increase the payoffs or aspirations of hubs in order to promote overall cooperation in public good games [100104]. The strategic positioning of initial cooperators can shorten the time to achieve cooperation, but their placement is non-trivial and depends on the exact game and the network structure [105]. In addition, given their universal presence, highly centralized structures and hierarchical networks have been analysed and the underlying asymmetries found to maintain cooperation in models [106] and in experimental work [107]. Stable hierarchies, however, could imply the lack of motivation and investment in cooperation from lower ranked individuals [108].

Theoretical models that investigated the evolution of cooperation in structured populations, such as in space or in lattices, observed the emergence of cooperation clusters in the population where cooperators meet other cooperators [109115]. Experimental research, in contrast, suggests that a structured population in itself is not sufficient to solve the problem of cooperation in human groups ([116119]; see also [120]). The mismatch could be caused by the low benefit to cost ratio in experiments [121], the share and positioning of initial cooperators in the network [105], the individual tendency to cooperate conditionally on the number of cooperative acts of others irrespective of payoff benefits [120] or learning the benefits of free-riding from others leading to a decay of cooperation in any structural setting.

Theoretical work and numerical simulations pinpoint dynamic strategy update rules that can promote cooperation in networks [98,122,123]. Unconditional, proportional or imperfect imitation strategies foster cooperation [109,124] more than innovative strategies, such as the myopic best response rule [125]. Mixing imitative and innovative dynamics is detrimental to cooperation near phase transitions and leads to the downfall of cooperation [126]. A general conclusion is that networks do not support or inhibit cooperation, but their impact depends on the micro-level mechanisms characterized by the strategy update rules individuals employ [124,127]. Results from statistical physics highlight the robust and universal features of phase transitions in problems of cooperation in networks [98,121,122,128,129], the impact of noise [130], mutations [131,132], punishment [129] and quenched distribution of types—which slows down relaxation towards the stationary state extremely [133]—therein.

This brings us to the role of dynamic social networks for the evolution of cooperation. People do not always interact or communicate with an unchanging set of partners. They can attempt to cut ties to previous interaction partners and form new ties (figure 1). This means not only that human interactions are embedded in social networks, but that social networks also change and evolve as a result of social interactions. Theoretical and experimental work has shown that dynamic social networks, labelled also as adaptive networks, in which agents can endogenously influence the network structure by cutting and forming social ties, foster cooperation [94,128,134,138150] and the positive impact of tie dynamics could even spill over to static parts of the network [151]. The impact of network structure on cooperation depends on the rules and characteristics of dynamic network updates. Cooperation can prevail also in highly unfavourable conditions if strategy adaptation is paired with selective creation of ties [152] or with random creation but selective deletion of ties [153]. Selection of links that ensure higher payoffs in combination with adaptive strategy update offer good chances for cooperation, leading to a hierarchical network [138]. The endogenous development of a strongly heterogeneous topology through mechanisms of growth and preferential attachment [89] in which cooperators can secure an advantageous structural position supports cooperation [145,154]. While the role of hubs connected to other hubs is central in this process as their behaviour is imitated with high probability [93,154], cooperators might be located also on nodes of intermediate degree unlike in static networks [155]. The key for the success of cooperation is that the combination of tie updates and strategy updates must ensure that cooperators directly avoid defectors [91,153,156,157] or benefit from a self-organized informal leadership structure [128,138,139,145].

Figure 1.

Figure 1.

Examples of how network dynamics can relate to cooperation and reputation. (a) Breaking relations (crossed ties) can be a form of punishment for defection (left) [134,135] or low reputation (right) [136], which could also originate from cooperation with defectors; (b) asking for gossip about future interaction partners might lead to creation of new ties (selection based on access to reliable information); (c) preferential attachment to individuals with high reputation (green node); (d) cooperation within a cohesive group of individuals might have negative externalities for out-group members, sharpening group boundaries and creating parochial competition [137] which might force bridging individuals (black node) to choose sides.

While most models assume that the network of interactions and the network of learning (strategy adoption) are identical and every relation is of equal strength, this is not necessarily the case [98,158,159]. Multiplex networks (cf. table 1) that represent the complex texture of relationships and model numerous layers that represent different social connections help cooperation endure even when the costs for exploitation are high [160]. Endogenous link updating in dynamic multiplex networks could lead to spontaneous symmetry breaking in cooperation levels across the layers [161163].

The heterogeneity in human exchanges depends on both the diverse social circles people engage in (workplace, family, friends and neighbourhoods) and the strength of the relationships they create. The strength of social ties, meaning the intensity of the relationship and the frequency of communications, acts as a mediator between the maintenance of cooperation and network dynamics: the more robust the links between cooperative people, the more cohesive the cluster of cooperators and the lower the tolerance of defective behaviours [164,165]. That is, through the possibility to choose the interaction partners by strengthening or weakening ties to other agents in a dynamic social network, cooperation can be sustained in both large and small populations [154]. Natural self-organization patterns can dynamically change a social network and induce the spontaneous emergence of cooperative clusters and help populations to become resistant to the invasion of free-riders [146,166,167]. Furthermore, when the network contains both positive and negative ties, network dynamics towards structural balance (e.g. ‘a friend of a friend becomes a friend’ and ‘the enemy of a friend becomes an enemy’) could efficiently drive the network towards in-group cooperation and cohesion [46,168170].

5. Reputation transmission in networks

Beyond the direct relationship between networks and cooperation, reputation-based cooperation is also shaped by networks (figure 2) and networks also change as a result of reputation processes. Reputation affects both cooperation and network formation [120,171].

Figure 2.

Figure 2.

Cooperation in networks and reputation. (a) Cooperation can emerge through direct reciprocity in dyadic relationships. (b) Individuals can transmit information on past interaction partners to third parties, influencing their behaviour and allowing the evolution of cooperation through indirect reciprocity. (c) Often, individuals are engaged in complex social networks with cooperative or uncooperative relationships. (d) The transmission of information can influence actions and relationships. Importantly, information in the form of gossip does not need to be correct, allowing strategic (mis)information. The transmission of reputational information through network ties raises the question of how conflicting information from different sources is integrated. (e) Agents that have a central position in the network have more channels to transmit information and, hence, may have more influence on the ties of other agents and the evolution of the network.

A useful framework to highlight how reputation is constructed in social networks comes from studies on the diffusion of information in networks [172], from the literature on learning in networks (e.g. [173]) and from network models of opinion dynamics (e.g. [174,175]). From this perspective, reputation in networks can be understood as arising from social influence, that is, as resulting from the communication between people that reinforces each other's views. A ‘shared evaluation’, as opposed to knowledge sharing, likely contains less certainty and requires more social proof, such as receiving the same information from multiple sources. This implies that for reputational information to get transmitted to others, a single source may not be sufficient [80]. Network models of reputation have been proposed to evaluate the reliability of multiple information sources [176178]. In contrast with models on contagious diseases and information in general, which spread only by contact (a simple contagion), reputational information may be a ‘complex contagion’, i.e. it requires confirmation from multiple sources to be believed and potentially acted upon [172;179, p. 35].

This means that an exposure to reputational information does not immediately imply its acceptance and transmission to others; rather it requires multiple sources of confirmation. This is especially true when the source of reputational information is someone socially distant (several links away in the network). Such verification may be particularly important in situations in which those involved may have strategic incentives to misrepresent reputational information (i.e. spread of false gossip). Therefore, networks that are characterized by high triadic closure, clustering and strong ties should facilitate complex contagions better than network structures with structural holes (open triads), low clustering and weak ties [179,180], because the former allow informational cross-checking and updating.

Extrapolating from this approach, it is likely that the transmission of reputational information might differ depending on the relevance and social (network) distance of the individual whose reputation is under discussion (target). Evidence shows that friendship and work ties influence individuals' propensity to engage in gossip [181,182]. Furthermore, the quantity and quality of the information shared shape individuals’ reputation: high gossip activity decrease people's popularity in the network [183], while gossipers acquire a moral reputation when sharing diagnostic and adequate information that helps to identify others as trustworthy or not [184]. Thus, gossip not only influences the reputation of actors in a social network as ‘good’ or ‘bad’ interaction partners. Individuals in a network can also acquire a reputation as trustworthy or untrustworthy information providers. Such meta-reputations may help to avoid the spreading of false gossip and reduce noise. Our empirical knowledge, however, is still limited on how reputation is disseminated in the social network and to what extent contagion is susceptible to noise in various network topologies, and why an individual could have different reputations in different subsets of the population, as well as how individuals' reputations change based on the information they share.

6. The interplay of networks, reputation and cooperation

The complex interplay of networks, reputation and cooperation is such that no simple directionality can be assumed, since all three elements influence each other. Consequently, attempts to grasp the dynamic connections between networks and reputation mechanisms and their impact on cooperation so far have been limited. This holds for integrative theoretical agendas in general, and formal modelling efforts in particular. Both have to disentangle not only the multiplex social ties connecting and the reputational information flowing between the actors in the triad (sender, receiver and target), but also their differential effect on each actor's reputation and cooperative behaviour. A major challenge is capturing the multitude and interrelatedness of potential mechanisms through which networks and reputation may affect cooperation (see [16] for a fuller discussion). Here, we review recent efforts at capturing this dynamic interplay, whether with models or by observational work.

(a) . Intragroup contexts

Some agent-based simulations, experimental studies and field studies have ventured into the coevolution of networks, reputations and cooperation. Partner selection plays a key role in these studies. For example, in a model where individuals interact in their local network, cut ties with individuals of low reputation and establish new relations with nearby individuals with the highest reputation (or with a random agent), free-riders get abandoned and stable and high levels of cooperation emerge parallel with a highly cohesive network structure [136]. This line of research follows up on early modelling work on ‘prisoner's dilemma networks' [185,186] and matches with the results of analytical work that analyses equilibria in games on networks [187].

Experiments also found that dynamics of partner updates based on reputational information lead to high assortativity and stable cooperation [147]. The knowledge of the network structure along with reputational information may be a driver of cooperation and imply the emergence of dense and clustered networks [171]. Other studies have found that cooperation levels increase when more frequent partner updating is allowed (e.g. [134,156]). Large-scale online experiments have also attempted to dissect the complex interplay of network dynamics, reputations and cooperation. It has been found that while reputation information is important for partner choice, it might not even be necessary, and cooperation can be sustained by network dynamics alone [27].

It is important to note that these coevolution models show that the boundary between reputation and punishment mechanisms is fuzzy at best. Some interpret indirect reciprocity models as in line with (passive) punishment models, since the exclusion of low-reputation players from future exchanges can be seen as a sanction [136]. This is also seen in experimental models with dynamic networks, in which this mechanism is referred to as ‘out-for-tat’ [185,186].

Field studies portray a less straightforward picture, owing to intertwined processes of social influence and partner selection (table 1, third row), and in particular, the complex coevolution of networks of cooperation and social status [188], or networks, gossip and reputation [189,190]. For example, a series of studies among employees in Dutch organizations found that partner selection strongly depends on three partner characteristics: (i) the degree to which a potential partner has disclosed reputational information about others, i.e. individuals prefer to build ties to those colleagues who have shared negative third-party gossip with them [183], (ii) the power reputation of potential partners, i.e. individuals prefer to build close interpersonal relations with those colleagues whom they deem informally influential [191], and (iii) the degree to which a potential partner actually occupies an influential brokerage position in the informal network [192]. Finally, partner selection is also strongly influenced by self-monitoring capacity of the selecting party [193], with high self-monitors being more likely than low self-monitors to befriend those whom they or others perceive as powerful [191].

(b) . Intergroup contexts

Intergroup contexts further complicate reputation dynamics and its role in establishing cooperation. A group is a bounded collection of interacting individuals who are interdependent to a certain degree [194]. In informal relations, group boundaries can be ambiguous, though they could be well approximated by detecting a relatively high density of network relations within the group and relatively few ties to members outside the group (e.g. [195198]). Often, a shared identity binds in-group members together, excluding others. Group membership is associated with parochial cooperation, i.e. high in-group cooperation and low out-group cooperation [137,199202]. These tendencies are supported by various theoretical accounts, such as social identity theory, self-categorization theory, bounded generalized reciprocity and parochial altruism ([203207]; for an overview of these theories, see [208]). Though several experiments have demonstrated the importance of social identification for in-group favouritism and in-group cooperation [200,201], experiments have also shown that people cooperate more both with in-group and out-group members when their reputation is at stake (e.g. [209211]). Not only do people earn reputation from their cooperation, but their reputation may also be affected by their group membership and the actions of group members, as group reputation can be formed from the aggregate of individual reputations [38,39,212214]. Such group reputations do not help to sustain cooperation with out-group members and generally lead to out-group discrimination [38,201].

One benefit of integrating network dynamics and cooperation is that groups do not have to be assumed to be exogenously given in the first place. Rather, models can allow for the dynamic emergence and dissolution of groups (e.g. [215]) and discrimination (e.g. [216]). Gross & De Dreu [46] provide an agent-based model where agents have personal information on others' cooperativeness, gossip and use the reputations learnt heuristically when deciding to cooperate with others. Applying the four reputation heuristics in structural balance theory, they found that groups emerged dynamically and displayed parochial cooperation; whereas reputation-based partner selection enhanced within-group cooperation, it impeded the emergence and stability of system-wide cooperation. Such models demonstrate that groups can emerge through learning, reputation and gossip, and that these constrain cooperation to certain clusters in a network.

These results are generally supported by behavioural experiments in the laboratory (e.g. [37,134]), and in real-world contexts (e.g. [217219]). Parochial structures, echo chambers and subgroup polarization may arise when networks and reputations evolve endogenously, increasing the likelihood of in-group loyalty, group-exclusive cooperation and intergroup competition. Further modelling and experimental studies are required, which will help elucidate when parochial cooperation becomes entrenched in processes such as group polarization, and when intergroup tolerance and cooperation are sustained.

7. Outlook

Reputation and networks provide paths to large-scale cooperation. Much theoretical and empirical research has been dedicated to understanding the role of reputation and networks for cooperation in isolation and apart from each other. Human cooperation, reputation, and network formation are clearly interrelated. Consequently, the complex causal linkages between reputation, cooperation and networks have gained increasing attention in the literature recently. Investigating the interplay of dynamic social networks and reputation information that is (imperfectly) transmitted through gossip is challenging, from both a theoretical and an empirical perspective. What complicates matters is that individuals can have strategic incentives to spread false gossip [6971], raising the question of how the validity of reputational information is secured in networks. As individuals associate with groups and attribute reputations also based on group stereotypes, group-bounded parochial cooperation could be the result of reputational dynamics. Investigating the complex interplay of social networks and reputation may, however, be fruitful as it could reveal unexpected emerging dynamics that help explain when or why cooperation remains group-bounded, in what situations networks ‘polarize’, or when cooperation may break down even under conditions that should theoretically favour cooperation. Here, we outline further avenues and open questions for future research, with a particular focus on the issue of complexity, which could be addressed by combining different methods, theoretical viewpoints and strengthening interdisciplinary collaborations.

One important open question is what determines the stability and efficiency of reputations and how eroding or developing reputations associates with the maintenance of cooperation. While cooperation has been associated with the convergence on consensual reputations, competition for reputation has also been shown to be an important driver of group-beneficial action. These two views are to a certain degree contradicting and could be reconciled in subsequent research. As competitive altruism theory suggests, competition could exhaust individual efforts and investments while the relative reputational positions remain unaltered, resulting in Red Queen dynamics [220] with the positive externality of large-scale cooperation [53,221223]. At the other extreme, we also have limited knowledge on those network processes that contribute to the maintenance of false reputations, their reinforcement and the maintenance of suboptimal collective outcomes. The many examples of the Emperor's Clothes are illustrated by theoretical and empirical work [224,225], though these studies are more focused on the emergence and persistence of unpopular norms and beliefs than on cooperation.

Cooperative behaviour may also be simultaneously motivated by both network structure and reputational concern. Observational studies by behavioural ecologists of food sharing and other forms of cooperative behaviour have broadly found that multiple mechanisms appear to be operating simultaneously (e.g. [226232]). Generous acts may help both to reinforce particular interpersonal relationships, and to build reputational standing [54,233236]. Taking an explicit networks perspective, studies of Lamaleran whale hunters [230,231] and of Canadian Inuit [232] found evidence for reputational signalling, reciprocity and clustering. Ready & Power [232] particularly note how norms of giving and of reciprocity can help to entrench those who wield particularly influential network positions and hold political power.

Another issue is relational multiplexity. When considering real social systems, it is nearly impossible to separate communicative acts and communication networks that may spread reputational information from the underlying social relations the same individuals may be involved in. In other words, networks of exchange and networks of information sharing—both of which may foster cooperation—are co-occurring and mutually overlapping. Social relations are generally multiplex, such that the pathways through which reputational content may flow will often be the same ones through which cooperative exchanges occur [160,162]. This entanglement inevitably adds further complexity to the process by which cooperation may be fostered. A multiplex network perspective may offer a unifying framework for further empirical investigations into the study of cooperation, reputation and networks, by defining different layers of ties in the same system, e.g. ‘who cooperates with whom’, ‘who attributes high/low reputation to whom’ and/or ‘who shares a reputation evaluation about a third party with whom’, ‘who is in a certain relationship (e.g. friendship, trust) with whom’, respectively, so that they can be studied simultaneously. Likewise, future research needs to consider the complex realities of group membership: individuals hold multiple identities [237] in multiplex social networks [238]. Appreciating this multiplexity—and the possibility for the same relationships to have both informational and material exchanges—will be crucial for further advancing our understanding of cooperation [238].

For all network and reputation processes in human cooperation, the social context, in particular, variations in the institutional and intergroup settings, matters. Cooperation is not only maintained through mechanisms of relational mobility and reputation, as outlined in this review. Groups also establish sanctioning systems based on implicit or explicit rules and develop norms of reciprocity [239241], which can be enforced through partner choice and ostracism, revealing a link between institutions and dynamic social networks. The degree to which networks can sustain or undermine cooperation through reputation, therefore, also depends on the institutional context [242], and on the acceptance and stability of informal and formal institutions that safeguard the maintenance of cooperation [243]. The institutional safeguards themselves have developed on the fundamentals of informal networks and reputation through human history [244247].

Individual differences are also important in understanding the adaptive function of reputation in networks. People differently manage their reputation depending on whether or not they value collective payoffs and the future [14], while there is also inter-individual variation in reputation domains (such as prosociality and competency, [248]), with concomitant effects on cooperation. Actors experience different socialization processes based on characteristics such as gender that influence the networks of exchange and information sharing described above. Although there is some evidence for overarching patterns, such as men are more likely to engage in competitive altruism than women (see [249] for a meta-analysis of sex differences), they might only hold for specific domains. What would also be informative is focusing on differences in status and relationship history within gender (e.g. [250]) or age group (e.g. [251]). Relatedly, research on the detection and recall of reputation and cooperative behaviours will elucidate proximate mechanisms underpinning the processes discussed in this review; see [46,120,252,253] for work on memory effects.

Finally, as our review has shown, empirical work in this field is based on a wide variety of methods. Agent-based simulation can extend analytical theoretical work in highlighting the macro consequences of micro mechanisms and structural dynamics (e.g. [68,254256]). Laboratory and field experiments can provide tests for simple hypotheses in controlled environments (e.g. [60,120,257,258]). Field experiments can use games that consider the complexity of individual and group relations in real-world settings (see [259]). The analysis of reputation mechanisms in online markets can provide insights into the efficiency of regulatory practices and could be used to test hypotheses on a massive scale (e.g. [260264]). Historical data and field observations (e.g. [218,235,265267]) could provide detailed insights on the build-up and functioning of reputation mechanisms for cooperation in unique contexts and could highlight both the universal character and myriad variegations across human societies. This methodological variety of empirical work demonstrates the added value of cross-disciplinarity. Future research is likely to benefit not only from further embracing this methodological pluralism, but also from strengthening the field's methodological and empirical foundations through more powerful mixed-method research designs.

Data accessibility

This article has no additional data.

Authors' contributions

K.T., J.G., M.T., S.L., A.R.K., E.A.P. and R.P.M.W. discussed the topic at the Lorentz Center, collected the relevant papers and wrote the review.

Competing interests

We declare we have no competing interests.

Funding

Participation at the workshop 'The language of cooperation: reputation and honest signaling' was facilitated by the Lorentz Center. K.T. and S.L. received funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union's research and innovation programme (grant agreement no. 648693). K.T. is supported by the National Research, Development and Innovation Office - NKFIH (OTKA) grant K 132250. R.P.M.W.'s contribution is part of the research programme Sustainable Cooperation - Roadmaps to Resilient Societies (SCOOP), funded by the Netherlands Organization for Scientific Research (NWO) and the Dutch Ministry of Education, Culture and Science (OCW) in the context of its 2017 Gravitation programme (grant number 024.003.025). S.L. is part of the relationship programme supported by The Medical Research Council and Scotland's Chief Scientist Office (MC_UU_00022/3) and with CSO funding of the Relationships programme (SPHSU18).

References

  • 1.Darwin C. 1859. On the origin of species. London, UK: John Murray. [Google Scholar]
  • 2.Dugatkin LA. 1997. Cooperation among animals: an evolutionary perspective. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 3.Maynard Smith J, Szathmáry E. 1997. The major transitions in evolution. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 4.Strassmann JE, Queller DC. 2010. The social organism: congresses, parties, and committees. Evolution 64, 605-616. ( 10.1111/j.1558-5646.2009.00929.x) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 5.Aktipis A, Maley CC. 2017. Cooperation and cheating as innovation: insights from cellular societies. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 372, 20160421. ( 10.1098/rstb.2016.0421) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Ratcliff WC, Herron M, Conlin PL, Libby E. 2017. Nascent life cycles and the emergence of higher-level individuality. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 372, 20160420. ( 10.1098/rstb.2016.0420) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Rand DG, Nowak MA. 2013. Human cooperation. Trends Cogn. Sci. 17, 413-425. ( 10.1016/j.tics.2013.06.003) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Raihani NJ, Bshary R. 2015. Why humans might help strangers. Front. Behav. Neurosci. 9, 39. ( 10.3389/fnbeh.2015.00039) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Alexander RD. 1979. Darwinism and human affairs. Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 10.Alexander RD. 1987. The biology of moral systems. New York, NY: Aldine de Gruyter. [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Nowak MA, Sigmund K. 1998. Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nature 393, 573-577. ( 10.1038/31225) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Nowak MA, Sigmund K. 2005. Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature 437, 1291-1298. ( 10.1038/nature04131) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 13.Wu J, Balliet D, Van Lange PA. 2016. Gossip versus punishment: the efficiency of reputation to promote and maintain cooperation. Scient. Rep. 6, 23919. ( 10.1038/srep23919) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Wu J, Balliet D, Van Lange PA. 2016. Reputation, gossip, and human cooperation. Social Pers. Psychol. Compass 10, 350-364. ( 10.1111/spc3.12255) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Tennie C, Frith U, Frith CD. 2010. Reputation management in the age of the world-wide web. Trends Cogn. Sci. 14, 482-488. ( 10.1016/j.tics.2010.07.003) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Giardini F, Wittek R. 2019. Gossip, reputation, and sustainable cooperation: sociological foundations. In The Oxford handbook of gossip and reputation (eds F Giardini, RPM Wittek), pp. 23-46. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Piazza J, Bering JM. 2008. Concerns about reputation via gossip promote generous allocations in an economic game. Evol. Hum. Behav. 29, 172-178. ( 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2007.12.002) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 18.Giardini F. 2012. Deterrence and transmission as mechanisms ensuring reliability of gossip. Cogn. Process. 13, 465-475. ( 10.1007/s10339-011-0421-0) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Barclay P. 2015. Reputation. In The handbook of evolutionary psychology (ed. DM Buss). John Wiley and Sons. ( 10.1002/9781119125563.evpsych233) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Dunbar RI. 2004. Gossip in evolutionary perspective. Rev. Gen. Psychol. 8, 100-110. ( 10.1037/1089-2680.8.2.100) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 21.Baumeister RF, Zhang L, Vohs KD. 2004. Gossip as cultural learning. Rev. Gen. Psychol. 8, 111-121. ( 10.1037/1089-2680.8.2.111) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 22.Sommerfeld RD, Krambeck HJ, Semmann D, Milinski M. 2007. Gossip as an alternative for direct observation in games of indirect reciprocity. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 104, 17 435-17 440. ( 10.1073/pnas.0704598104) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 23.Beersma B, Van Kleef GA. 2011. How the grapevine keeps you in line: gossip increases contributions to the group. Social Psychol. Pers. Sci. 2, 642-649. ( 10.1177/1948550611405073) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 24.Beersma B, Van Kleef GA. 2012. Why people gossip: an empirical analysis of social motives, antecedents, and consequences. J. Appl. Social Psychol. 42, 2640-2670. ( 10.1111/j.1559-1816.2012.00956.x) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Feinberg M, Willer R, Schultz M. 2014. Gossip and ostracism promote cooperation in groups. Psychol. Sci. 25, 656-664. ( 10.1177/0956797613510184) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 26.Reynolds T, Baumeister RF, Maner JK. 2018. Competitive reputation manipulation: women strategically transmit social information about romantic rivals. J. Exp. Social Psychol. 78, 195-209. ( 10.1016/j.jesp.2018.03.011) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 27.Melamed D, Harrell A, Simpson B. 2018. Cooperation, clustering, and assortative mixing in dynamic networks. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 115, 951-956. ( 10.1073/pnas.1715357115) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 28.Hamilton WD. 1964. The genetical evolution of social behaviour I. J. Theor. Biol. 7, 1-16. ( 10.1016/0022-5193(64)90038-4) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 29.Hamilton WD. 1964. The genetical evolution of social behaviour II. J. Theor. Biol. 7, 17-52. ( 10.1016/0022-5193(64)90039-6) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 30.Kay T, Keller L, Lehmann L. 2020. The evolution of altruism and the serial rediscovery of the role of relatedness. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 117, 28 894-28 898. ( 10.1073/pnas.2013596117) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 31.Trivers RL. 1971. The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Q. Rev. Biol. 46, 35-57. ( 10.1086/406755) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 32.Axelrod R, Hamilton WD. 1981. The evolution of cooperation. Science 211, 1390-1396. ( 10.1126/science.7466396) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 33.Axelrod R. 1984. The evolution of cooperation. New York, NY: Basic Books. [Google Scholar]
  • 34.Wedekind C, Milinski M. 2000. Cooperation through image scoring in humans. Science 288, 850-852. ( 10.1126/science.288.5467.850) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 35.Milinski M. 2016. Reputation, a universal currency for human social interactions. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 371, 20150100. ( 10.1098/rstb.2015.0100) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 36.Diekmann A, Jann B, Wyder D. 2009. Trust and reputation in internet auctions. In eTrust: forming relationships in the online world (eds Cook KS, Snijders C, Buskens V, Cheshire C), pp. 139-165. New York, NY: Russel Sage Foundation. [Google Scholar]
  • 37.Antonioni A, Sánchez A, Tomassini M. 2016. Cooperation survives and cheating pays in a dynamic network structure with unreliable reputation. Scient. Rep. 6, 27160. ( 10.1038/srep27160) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 38.Duca S, Nax HH. 2018. Groups and scores: the decline of cooperation. J. R. Soc. Interface 15, 20180158. ( 10.1098/rsif.2018.0158) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 39.Nax HH, Perc M, Szolnoki A, Helbing D. 2015. Stability of cooperation under image scoring in group interactions. Scient. Rep. 5, 12145. ( 10.1038/srep12145) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 40.Milinski M, Semmann D, Bakker TC, Krambeck HJ. 2001. Cooperation through indirect reciprocity: image scoring or standing strategy? Proc. R. Soc. Lond. B 268, 2495-2501. ( 10.1098/rspb.2001.1809) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 41.Panchanathan K, Boyd R. 2003. A tale of two defectors: the importance of standing for evolution of indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 224, 115-126. ( 10.1016/S0022-5193(03)00154-1) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 42.Pacheco JM, Santos FC, Chalub FAC. 2006. Stern-judging: a simple, successful norm which promotes cooperation under indirect reciprocity. PLoS Comput. Biol. 2, e178. ( 10.1371/journal.pcbi.0020178) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 43.Santos FP, Santos FC, Pacheco JM. 2018. Social norm complexity and past reputations in the evolution of cooperation. Nature 555, 242–245. ( 10.1038/nature25763) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 44.Ohtsuki H, Iwasa Y. 2004. How should we define goodness?—Reputation dynamics in indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 231, 107-120. ( 10.1016/j.jtbi.2004.06.005) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 45.Ohtsuki H, Iwasa Y. 2006. The leading eight: social norms that can maintain cooperation by indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 239, 435-444. ( 10.1016/j.jtbi.2005.08.008) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 46.Gross J, De Dreu CK. 2019. The rise and fall of cooperation through reputation and group polarization. Nat. Commun. 10, 1. ( 10.1038/s41467-018-07882-8) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 47.Quan J, Tang C, Wang X. 2021. Reputation-based discount effect in imitation on the evolution of cooperation in spatial public goods games. Physica A 563, 125488. ( 10.1016/j.physa.2020.125488) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 48.Ahn TK, Esarey J, Scholz JT. 2009. Reputation and cooperation in voluntary exchanges: comparing local and central institutions. J. Polit. 71, 398-413. ( 10.1017/s0022381609090355) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 49.Sylwester K, Roberts G. 2013. Reputation-based partner choice is an effective alternative to indirect reciprocity in solving social dilemmas. Evol. Hum. Behav. 34, 201-206. ( 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2012.11.009) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 50.Capraro V, Giardini F, Vilone D, Paolucci M. 2016. Partner selection supported by opaque reputation promotes cooperative behavior. Judgm. Decis. Mak. 11, 589-600. [Google Scholar]
  • 51.Wu J, Balliet D, Peperkoorn LS, Romano A, Van Lange PA. 2020. Cooperation in groups of different sizes: the effects of punishment and reputation-based partner choice. Front. Psychol. 10, 2956. ( 10.3389/fpsyg.2019.02956) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 52.Noë R, Hammerstein P. 1994. Biological markets: supply and demand determine the effect of partner choice in cooperation, mutualism and mating. Behav. Ecol. Sociobiol. 35, 1-11. ( 10.1007/BF00167053) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 53.Roberts G. 1998. Competitive altruism: from reciprocity to the handicap principle. Proc. R. Soc. Lond. B 265, 427-431. ( 10.1098/rspb.1998.0312) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 54.Barclay P, Willer R. 2007. Partner choice creates competitive altruism in humans. Proc. R. Soc. B 274, 749-753. ( 10.1098/rspb.2006.0209) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 55.Barclay P. 2013. Strategies for cooperation in biological markets, especially for humans. Evol. Hum. Behav. 34, 164-175. ( 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2013.02.002) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 56.Barclay P. 2016. Biological markets and the effects of partner choice on cooperation and friendship. Curr. Opin. Psychol. 7, 33-38. ( 10.1016/j.copsyc.2015.07.012) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 57.Ohtsuki H, Iwasa Y, Nowak MA. 2015. Reputation effects in public and private interactions. PLoS Comput. Biol. 11, e1004527. ( 10.1371/journal.pcbi.1004527) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 58.Hilbe C, Schmid L, Tkadlec J, Chatterjee K, Nowak MA. 2018. Indirect reciprocity with private, noisy, and incomplete information. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 115, 12 241-12 246. ( 10.1073/pnas.1810565115) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 59.Yang G, Csikász-Nagy A, Waites W, Cavaliere M. 2020. Information cascades and the collapse of cooperation. Scient. Rep. 10, 8004. ( 10.1038/s41598-020-64800-z) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 60.Samu F, Számadó S, Takács K. 2020. Scarce and directly beneficial reputations support cooperation. Scient. Rep. 10, 11486. ( 10.1038/s41598-020-68123-x) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 61.Samu F, Takács K. 2021. Evaluating mechanisms that could support credible reputations and cooperation: cross-checking and social bonding. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 376, 20200302. ( 10.1098/rstb.2020.0302) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 62.Podder S, Righi S, Takács K. 2021. Local reputation, local selection, and the leading eight norms. Scient. Rep. 11, 16560. ( 10.1038/s41598-021-95130-3) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 63.Sommerfeld RD, Krambeck HJ, Milinski M. 2008. Multiple gossip statements and their effect on reputation and trustworthiness. Proc. R. Soc. B 275, 2529-2536. ( 10.1098/rspb.2008.0762) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 64.Feinberg M, Willer R, Stellar J, Keltner D. 2012. The virtues of gossip: reputational information sharing as prosocial behavior. J. Pers. Social Psychol. 102, 1015. ( 10.1037/a0026650) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 65.Fehr D, Sutter M. 2019. Gossip and the efficiency of interactions. Games Econ. Behav. 113, 448-460. ( 10.1016/j.geb.2018.10.003) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 66.Dores Cruz TD, Nieper AS, Testori M, Martinescu E, Beersma B. 2021. An integrative definition and framework to study gossip. Group Org. Manage. 46, 252–285. ( 10.1177/1059601121992887) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 67.Wittek R, Wielers R. 1998. Gossip in organizations. Comput. Math. Org. Theory 4, 189-204. ( 10.1023/A:1009636325582) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 68.Giardini F, Vilone D. 2016. Evolution of gossip-based indirect reciprocity on a bipartite network. Scient. Rep. 6, 37931. ( 10.1038/srep37931) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 69.Hess NH, Hagen EH. 2006. Psychological adaptations for assessing gossip veracity. Hum. Nat. 17, 337-354. ( 10.1007/s12110-006-1013-z) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 70.Giardini F, Wittek RPM. 2019. Silence is golden. Six reasons inhibiting the spread of third-party gossip. Front. Psychol. 10, 1120. ( 10.3389/fpsyg.2019.01120) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 71.Peters K, Fonseca MA. 2020. Truth, lies, and gossip. Psychol. Sci. 31, 702-714. ( 10.1177/0956797620916708) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 72.Hess NH, Hagen EH. 2021. Competitive gossip: the impact of domain, resource value, resource scarcity and coalitions. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 376, 20200305. ( 10.1098/rstb.2020.0305) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 73.Wang Z, Wang L, Yin Z-Y, Xia C-Y. 2012. Inferring reputation promotes the evolution of cooperation in spatial social dilemma games. PLoS ONE 7, e40218. ( 10.1371/journal.pone.0040218) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 74.Walmsley J, O'Madagain C. 2020. The worst-motive fallacy: a negativity bias in motive attribution. Psychol. Sci. 31, 1430–1438. ( 10.1177/0956797620954492) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 75.Lee SH, Barnes CM. 2021. An attributional process model of workplace gossip. J. Appl. Psychol. 106, 300–316. ( 10.1037/apl0000504) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 76.Watts DJ, Strogatz SH. 1988. Collective dynamics of ‘small-world’ networks. Nature 393, 440–442. ( 10.1038/30918) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 77.Watts DJ. 1999. Small worlds. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 78.McPherson M, Smith-Lovin L, Cook JM. 2001. Birds of a feather: homophily in social networks. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 27, 415-444. ( 10.1146/annurev.soc.27.1.415) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 79.Steglich C, Snijders TA, Pearson M. 2010. Dynamic networks and behavior: separating selection from influence. Sociol. Methodol. 40, 329-393. ( 10.1111/j.1467-9531.2010.01225.x) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 80.Righi S, Takács K. 2018. Social closure and the evolution of cooperation via indirect reciprocity. Scient. Rep. 8, 11149. ( 10.1038/s41598-018-29290-0) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 81.Santos FC, Pacheco JM. 2005. Scale-free networks provide a unifying framework for the emergence of cooperation. Phys. Rev. Lett. 95, 098104. ( 10.1103/PhysRevLett.95.098104) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 82.Jansen VAA, van Baalen M. 2006. Altruism through beard chromodynamics. Nature 440, 663-666. ( 10.1038/nature04387) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 83.Fu F, Chen X, Liu L, Wang L. 2007. Social dilemmas in an online social network: the structure and evolution of cooperation. Phys. Lett. A 371, 58-64. ( 10.1016/j.physleta.2007.05.116) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 84.Vukov J, Santos FC, Pacheco JM. 2012. Cognitive strategies take advantage of the cooperative potential of heterogeneous networks. New J. Phys. 14, 063031. ( 10.1088/1367-2630/14/6/063031) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 85.Rand DG, Nowak MA, Fowler JH, Christakis NA. 2014. Static network structure can stabilize human cooperation. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 111, 17 093-17 098. ( 10.1073/pnas.1400406111) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 86.Lo Iacono S. 2018. Does community social embeddedness promote generalized trust? An experimental test of the spillover effect. Social Sci. Res. 73, 126-145. ( 10.1016/j.ssresearch.2018.03.001) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 87.Testori M, Hoyle RB, Eisenbarth H. 2019. How group composition affects cooperation in fixed networks: can psychopathic traits influence group dynamics? R. Soc. Open Sci. 6, 181329. ( 10.1098/rsos.181329) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 88.Ohtsuki H, Hauert C, Lieberman E, Nowak MA. 2006. A simple rule for the evolution of cooperation on graphs and social networks. Nature 441, 502-505. ( 10.1038/nature04605) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 89.Barabási AL, Albert R. 1999. Emergence of scaling in random networks. Science 286, 509-512. ( 10.1126/science.286.5439.509) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 90.Poncela J, Gómez-Gardeñes J, Floría LM, Moreno Y. 2007. Robustness of cooperation in the evolutionary prisoner's dilemma on complex networks. New J. Phys. 9, 184. ( 10.1088/1367-2630/9/6/184) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 91.Santos FC, Pacheco JM, Lenaerts T. 2006. Evolutionary dynamics of social dilemmas in structured heterogeneous populations. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 103, 3490-3494. ( 10.1073/pnas.0508201103) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 92.Gómez-Gardeñes J, Campillo M, Floría LM, Moreno Y. 2007. Dynamical organization of cooperation in complex topologies. Phys. Rev. Lett. 98, 108103. ( 10.1103/PhysRevLett.98.108103) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 93.Santos FC, Santos MD, Pacheco JM. 2008. Social diversity promotes the emergence of cooperation in public goods games. Nature 454, 213-216. ( 10.1038/nature06940) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 94.Perc M. 2009. Evolution of cooperation on scale-free networks subject to error and attack. New J. Phys. 11, 033027. ( 10.1088/1367-2630/11/3/033027) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 95.Watts DJ, Strogatz SH. 1998. Collective dynamics of ‘small-world’ networks. Nature 393, 440-442. ( 10.1038/30918) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 96.Santos FC, Rodrigues JF, Pacheco JM. 2005. Epidemic spreading and cooperation dynamics on homogeneous small-world networks. Phys. Rev. E 72, 056128. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.72.056128) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 97.Pavlogiannis A, Tkadlec J, Chatterjee K, Nowak MA. 2017. Amplification on undirected population structures: comets beat stars. Scient. Rep. 7, 82. ( 10.1038/s41598-017-00107-w) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 98.Szabó G, Fáth G. 2007. Evolutionary games on graphs. Phys. Rep. 446, 97-216. ( 10.1016/j.physrep.2007.04.004) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 99.Rong Z, Yang HX, Wang WX. 2010. Feedback reciprocity mechanism promotes the cooperation of highly clustered scale-free networks. Phys. Rev. E 82, 047101. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.82.047101) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 100.Perc M, Gómez-Gardeñes J, Szolnoki A, Floría LM, Moreno Y. 2013. Evolutionary dynamics of group interactions on structured populations: a review. J. R. Soc. Interface 10, 20120997. ( 10.1098/rsif.2012.0997) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 101.Cao XB, Du WB, Rong ZH. 2010. The evolutionary public goods game on scale-free networks with heterogeneous investment. Physica A 389, 1273-1280. ( 10.1016/j.physa.2009.11.044) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 102.Lei C, Wu T, Jia JY, Cong R, Wang L. 2010. Heterogeneity of allocation promotes cooperation in public goods games. Physica A 389, 4708-4714. ( 10.1016/j.physa.2010.06.002) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 103.Zhang H, Yang H, Du W, Wang B, Cao X. 2010. Evolutionary public goods games on scale-free networks with unequal payoff allocation mechanism. Physica A 389, 1099-1104. ( 10.1016/j.physa.2009.11.029) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 104.Yang HX, Rong Z, Lu PM, Zeng YZ. 2012. Effects of aspiration on public cooperation in structured populations. Physica A 391, 4043-4049. ( 10.1016/j.physa.2012.03.018) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 105.Yang G, Cavaliere M, Zhu C, Perc M. 2021. Strategically positioning cooperators can facilitate the contagion of cooperation. Scient. Rep. 11, 1. ( 10.1038/s41598-020-79139-8) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 106.Lieberman E, Hauert C, Nowak MA. 2005. Evolutionary dynamics on graphs. Nature 433, 312-316. ( 10.1038/nature03204) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 107.Molho C, Balliet D, Wu J. 2019. Hierarchy, power, and strategies to promote cooperation in social dilemmas. Games 10, 12. ( 10.3390/g10010012) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 108.Cronin KA, Acheson DJ, Hernández P, Sánchez A. 2015. Hierarchy is detrimental for human cooperation. Scient. Rep. 5, 18634. ( 10.1038/srep18634) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 109.Nowak MA, May RM. 1992. Evolutionary games and spatial chaos. Nature 359, 826-829. ( 10.1038/359826a0) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 110.Nowak MA, May RM. 1993. The spatial dilemmas of evolution. Int. J. Bifurcation Chaos 3, 35-78. ( 10.1142/S0218127493000040) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 111.Szabó G, Vukov J, Szolnoki A. 2005. Phase diagrams for an evolutionary prisoner's dilemma game on two-dimensional lattices. Phys. Rev. E 72, 047107. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.72.047107) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 112.Vukov J, Szabó G. 2005. Evolutionary prisoner's dilemma game on hierarchical lattices. Phys. Rev. E 71, 036133. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.71.036133) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 113.Doebeli M, Hauert C. 2005. Models of cooperation based on the Prisoner's Dilemma and the Snowdrift game. Ecol. Lett. 8, 748-766. ( 10.1111/j.1461-0248.2005.00773.x) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 114.Németh A, Takács K. 2007. The evolution of altruism in spatially structured populations. J. Artif. Soc. Social Simul. 10, 4. [Google Scholar]
  • 115.Nowak MA, Tarnita CE, Antal T. 2010. Evolutionary dynamics in structured populations. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 365, 19-30. ( 10.1098/rstb.2009.0215) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 116.Traulsen A, Semmann D, Sommerfeld RD, Krambeck HJ, Milinski M. 2010. Human strategy updating in evolutionary games. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 107, 2962-2966. ( 10.1073/pnas.0912515107) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 117.Grujić J, Fosco C, Araujo L, Cuesta JA, Sánchez A. 2010. Social experiments in the mesoscale: humans playing a spatial prisoner's dilemma. PLoS ONE 5, e13749. ( 10.1371/journal.pone.0013749) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 118.Grujić J, Röhl T, Semmann D, Milinski M, Traulsen A. 2012. Consistent strategy updating in spatial and non-spatial behavioral experiments does not promote cooperation in social networks. PLoS ONE 7, e47718. ( 10.1371/journal.pone.0047718) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 119.Gracia-Lázaro C, Ferrer A, Ruiz G, Tarancón A, Cuesta JA, Sánchez A, Moreno Y. 2012. Heterogeneous networks do not promote cooperation when humans play a Prisoner's Dilemma. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 109, 12 922-12 926. ( 10.1073/pnas.1206681109) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 120.Cuesta JA, Gracia-Lázaro C, Ferrer A, Moreno Y, Sánchez A. 2015. Reputation drives cooperative behaviour and network formation in human groups. Scient. Rep. 5, 7843. ( 10.1038/srep07843) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 121.Perc M, Jordan JJ, Rand DG, Wang Z, Boccaletti S, Szolnoki A. 2017. Statistical physics of human cooperation. Phys. Rep. 687, 1-51. ( 10.1016/j.physrep.2017.05.004) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 122.Roca CP, Cuesta JA, Sánchez A. 2009. Evolutionary game theory: temporal and spatial effects beyond replicator dynamics. Phys. Life Rev. 6, 208-249. ( 10.1016/j.plrev.2009.08.001) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 123.Amaral MA, Perc M, Wardil L, Szolnoki A, da Silva Júnior EJ, da Silva JK. 2017. Role-separating ordering in social dilemmas controlled by topological frustration. Phys. Rev. E 95, 032307. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.95.032307) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 124.Roca CP, Sánchez A, Cuesta JA. 2012. Individual strategy update and emergence of cooperation in social networks. J. Math. Sociol. 36, 1-21. ( 10.1080/0022250X.2010.520830) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 125.Roca CP, Cuesta JA, Sánchez A. 2009. Promotion of cooperation on networks? The myopic best response case. Eur. Phys. J. B 71, 587-595. ( 10.1140/epjb/e2009-00189-0) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 126.Amaral MA, Javarone MA. 2018. Heterogeneous update mechanisms in evolutionary games: mixing innovative and imitative dynamics. Phys. Rev. E 97, 042305. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.97.042305) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 127.Gómez-Gardeñes J, Vilone D, Sánchez A. 2011. Disentangling social and group heterogeneities: public goods games on complex networks. EPL (Europhys. Lett.) 95, 68003. ( 10.1209/0295-5075/95/68003) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 128.Perc M, Szolnoki A. 2010. Coevolutionary games—a mini review. Biosystems 99, 109-125. ( 10.1016/j.biosystems.2009.10.003) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 129.Perc M. 2016. Phase transitions in models of human cooperation. Phys. Lett. A 380, 2803-2808. ( 10.1016/j.physleta.2016.06.017) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 130.Vukov J, Szabó G, Szolnoki A. 2006. Cooperation in the noisy case: prisoner's dilemma game on two types of regular random graphs. Phys. Rev. E 73, 067103. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.73.067103) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 131.Ichinose G, Satotani Y, Sayama H. 2018. How mutation alters the evolutionary dynamics of cooperation on networks. New J. Phys. 20, 053049. ( 10.1088/1367-2630/aac2a7) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 132.Wang X, Duh M, Perc M. 2020. Robust cooperation against mutations via costly expulsion. EPL (Europhys. Lett.) 132, 38001. ( 10.1209/0295-5075/132/38001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 133.Droz M, Szwabiński J, Szabó G. 2009. Motion of influential players can support cooperation in prisoner's dilemma. Eur. Phys. J. B 71, 579-585. ( 10.1140/epjb/e2009-00160-1) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 134.Rand DG, Arbesman S, Christakis NA. 2011. Dynamic social networks promote cooperation in experiments with humans. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 108, 19 193-19 198. ( 10.1073/pnas.1108243108) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 135.Takács K, Janky B, Flache A. 2008. Collective action and network change. Social Netw. 30, 177-189. ( 10.1016/j.socnet.2008.02.003) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 136.Fu F, Hauert C, Nowak MA, Wang L. 2008. Reputation-based partner choice promotes cooperation in social networks. Phys. Rev. E 78, 026117. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.78.026117) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 137.De Dreu CK, Gross J, Fariña A, Ma Y. 2020. Group cooperation, carrying-capacity stress, and intergroup conflict. Trends Cogn. Sci. 24, 760-776. ( 10.1016/j.tics.2020.06.005) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 138.Zimmermann MG, Eguíluz VM, San Miguel M. 2004. Coevolution of dynamical states and interactions in dynamic networks. Phys. Rev. E 69, 065102. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.69.065102) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 139.Eguíluz VM, Zimmermann MG, Cela-Conde CJ, Miguel MS. 2005. Cooperation and the emergence of role differentiation in the dynamics of social networks. Am. J. Sociol. 110, 977-1008. ( 10.1086/428716) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 140.Santos FC, Pacheco JM, Lenaerts T. 2006. Cooperation prevails when individuals adjust their social ties. PLoS Comput. Biol. 2, e140. ( 10.1371/journal.pcbi.0020140) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 141.Pacheco JM, Traulsen A, Nowak MA. 2006. Coevolution of strategy and structure in complex networks with dynamical linking. Phys. Rev. Lett. 97, 258103. ( 10.1103/PhysRevLett.97.258103) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 142.Masuda N. 2007. Participation costs dismiss the advantage of heterogeneous networks in evolution of cooperation. Proc. R. Soc. B 274, 1815-1821. ( 10.1098/rspb.2007.0294) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 143.Wang S, Szalay MS, Zhang C, Csermely P. 2008. Learning and innovative elements of strategy adoption rules expand cooperative network topologies. PLoS ONE 3, e1917. ( 10.1371/journal.pone.0001917) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 144.Pacheco JM, Pinheiro FL, Santos FC. 2009. Population structure induces a symmetry breaking favoring the emergence of cooperation. PLoS Comput. Biol. 5, e1000596. ( 10.1371/journal.pcbi.1000596) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 145.Zschaler G, Traulsen A, Gross T. 2010. A homoclinic route to asymptotic full cooperation in adaptive networks and its failure. New J. Phys. 12, 093015. ( 10.1088/1367-2630/12/9/093015) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 146.Fehl K, van der Post DJ, Semmann D. 2011. Co-evolution of behaviour and social network structure promotes human cooperation. Ecol. Lett. 14, 546-551. ( 10.1111/j.1461-0248.2011.01615.x) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 147.Wang J, Suri S, Watts DJ. 2012. Cooperation and assortativity with dynamic partner updating. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 109, 14 363-14 368. ( 10.1073/pnas.1120867109) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 148.Shirado H, Fu F, Fowler JH, Christakis NA. 2013. Quality versus quantity of social ties in experimental cooperative networks. Nat. Commun. 4, 2814. ( 10.1038/ncomms3814) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 149.Wardil L, Hauert C. 2014. Origin and structure of dynamic cooperative networks. Scient. Rep. 4, 5725. ( 10.1038/srep05725) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 150.McAvoy A, Allen B, Nowak MA. 2020. Social goods dilemmas in heterogeneous societies. Nat. Hum. Behav. 4, 819-831. ( 10.1038/s41562-020-0881-2) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 151.Harrell A, Melamed D, Simpson B. 2018. The strength of dynamic ties: the ability to alter some ties promotes cooperation in those that cannot be altered. Sci. Adv. 4, eaau9109. ( 10.1126/sciadv.aau9109) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 152.Szolnoki A, Perc M, Danku Z. 2008. Making new connections towards cooperation in the prisoner's dilemma game. EPL (Europhys. Lett.) 84, 50007. ( 10.1209/0295-5075/84/50007) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 153.Szolnoki A, Perc M. 2009. Resolving social dilemmas on evolving random networks. EPL (Europhys. Lett.) 86, 30007. ( 10.1209/0295-5075/86/30007) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 154.Santos FC, Rodrigues JF, Pacheco JM. 2006. Graph topology plays a determinant role in the evolution of cooperation. Proc. R. Soc. B 273, 51-55. ( 10.1098/rspb.2005.3272) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 155.Poncela J, Gómez-Gardeñes J, Floría LM, Sánchez A, Moreno Y. 2008. Complex cooperative networks from evolutionary preferential attachment. PLoS ONE 3, e2449. ( 10.1371/journal.pone.0002449) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 156.Hanaki N, Peterhansl A, Dodds PS, Watts DJ. 2007. Cooperation in evolving social networks. Manage. Sci. 53, 1036-1050. ( 10.1287/mnsc.1060.0625) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 157.Fu F, Wu T, Wang L. 2009. Partner switching stabilizes cooperation in coevolutionary prisoner's dilemma. Phys. Rev. E 79, 036101. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.79.036101) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 158.Ohtsuki H, Nowak MA, Pacheco JM. 2007. Breaking the symmetry between interaction and replacement in evolutionary dynamics on graphs. Phys. Rev. Lett. 98, 108106. ( 10.1103/PhysRevLett.98.108106) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 159.Ohtsuki H, Pacheco JM, Nowak MA. 2007. Evolutionary graph theory: breaking the symmetry between interaction and replacement. J. Theor. Biol. 246, 681-694. ( 10.1016/j.jtbi.2007.01.024) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 160.Gómez-Gardeñes J, Reinares I, Arenas A, Floría LM. 2012. Evolution of cooperation in multiplex networks. Scient. Rep. 2, 620. ( 10.1038/srep00620) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 161.Jin Q, Wang L, Xia CY, Wang Z. 2014. Spontaneous symmetry breaking in interdependent networked game. Scient. Rep. 4, 4095. ( 10.1038/srep04095) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 162.Battiston F, Perc M, Latora V. 2017. Determinants of public cooperation in multiplex networks. New J. Phys. 19, 073017. ( 10.1088/1367-2630/aa6ea1) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 163.Takesue H. 2021. Symmetry breaking in the Prisoner's Dilemma on two-layer dynamic multiplex networks. Appl. Math. Comput. 388, 125543. ( 10.1016/j.amc.2020.125543) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 164.Wu B, Zhou D, Fu F, Luo Q, Wang L, Traulsen A. 2010. Evolution of cooperation on stochastic dynamical networks. PLoS ONE 5, e11187. ( 10.1371/journal.pone.0011187) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 165.Melamed D, Simpson B. 2016. Strong ties promote the evolution of cooperation in dynamic networks. Social Netw. 45, 32-44. ( 10.1016/j.socnet.2015.11.001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 166.Szolnoki A, Perc M. 2009. Promoting cooperation in social dilemmas via simple coevolutionary rules. Eur. Phys. J. B 67, 337-344. ( 10.1140/epjb/e2008-00470-8) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 167.Szolnoki A, Perc M. 2009. Emergence of multilevel selection in the Prisoner's Dilemma game on coevolving random networks. New J. Phys. 11, 093033. ( 10.1088/1367-2630/11/9/093033) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 168.Traag VA, Van Dooren P, De Leenheer P. 2013. Dynamical models explaining social balance and evolution of cooperation. PLoS ONE 8, e60063. ( 10.1371/journal.pone.0060063) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 169.Righi S, Takács K. 2014. Emotional strategies as catalysts for cooperation in signed networks. Adv. Complex Syst. 17, 1450011. ( 10.1142/S0219525914500118) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 170.He X, Du H, Cai M, Feldman MW. 2018. The evolution of cooperation in signed networks under the impact of structural balance. PloS ONE 13, e0205084. ( 10.1371/journal.pone.0205084) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 171.Gallo E, Yan C. 2015. The effects of reputational and social knowledge on cooperation. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 112, 3647-3652. ( 10.1073/pnas.1415883112) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 172.Centola D. 2018. How behavior spreads: the science of complex contagions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 173.Goyal S. 2011. Learning in networks. In Handbook of social economics (eds J Benhabib, A Bisin, MO Jackson), vol. 1, pp. 679-727. San Diego, CA: Elsevier North Holland. ( 10.1016/B978-0-444-53187-2.00015-2) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 174.DeGroot MH. 1974. Reaching a consensus. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 69, 118-121. ( 10.1080/01621459.1974.10480137) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 175.Quattrociocchi W, Caldarelli G, Scala A. 2014. Opinion dynamics on interacting networks: media competition and social influence. Scient. Rep. 4, 4938. ( 10.1038/srep04938) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 176.Barber KS, Kim J. 2001. Belief revision process based on trust: agents evaluating reputation of information sources. In Trust in cyber-societies (eds Falcone R, Singh M, Tan Y-H), pp. 73–82. Berlin, Germany: Springer. [Google Scholar]
  • 177.Teacey WL, Patel J, Jennings NR, Luck M. 2006. Travos: trust and reputation in the context of inaccurate information sources. Auton. Agent. Multi-Agent Sys. 12, 183–198. ( 10.1007/s10458-006-5952-x) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 178.Craik KH. 2008. Reputation: a network interpretation. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 179.Centola D, Macy M. 2007. Complex contagions and the weakness of long ties. Am. J. Sociol. 113, 702-734. ( 10.1086/521848) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 180.Centola D. 2010. The spread of behavior in an online social network experiment. Science 329, 1194-1197. ( 10.1126/science.1185231) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 181.Grosser TJ, Lopez-Kidwell V, Labianca G. 2010. A social network analysis of positive and negative gossip in organizational life. Group Org. Manage. 35, 177–212. ( 10.1177/1059601109360391) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 182.Ellwardt L, Wittek RPM, Wielers R. 2012. Talking about the boss: effects of generalized and interpersonal trust on workplace gossip. Group Org. Manage. 37, 521-549. ( 10.1177/1059601112450607) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 183.Ellwardt L, Steglich C, Wittek R. 2012. The co-evolution of gossip and friendship in workplace social networks. Social Netw. 34, 623-633. ( 10.1016/j.socnet.2012.07.002) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 184.Peters K, Kashima Y. 2015. Bad habit or social good? How perceptions of gossiper morality are related to gossip content. Eur. J. Soc. Psychol. 45, 784–798. ( 10.1002/ejsp.2123) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 185.Yamagishi T, Hayashi N, Jin N. 1994. Prisoner's dilemma networks: selection strategy versus action strategy. In Social dilemmas and cooperation (eds Schulz U, Albers W, Mueller U), pp. 233-250. Berlin, Germany: Springer. [Google Scholar]
  • 186.Hayashi N, Yamagishi T. 1998. Selective play: choosing partners in an uncertain world. Pers. Social Psychol. Rev. 2, 276. ( 10.1207/s15327957pspr0204_4) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 187.Jackson MO, Rodriguez-Barraquer T, Tan X. 2012. Social capital and social quilts: network patterns of favor exchange. Am. Econ. Rev. 102, 1857-1897. ( 10.1257/aer.102.5.1857) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 188.von Rueden CR, Redhead D, O'Gorman R, Kaplan H, Gurven M. 2019. The dynamics of men's cooperation and social status in a small-scale society. Proc. R. Soc. B 286, 20191367. ( 10.1098/rspb.2019.1367) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 189.Kisfalusi D, Takács K, Pál J. 2019. Gossip and reputation in adolescent networks. In Oxford handbook on gossip and reputation (eds Giardini F, Wittek RPM), pp. 359-379. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 190.Ellwardt L. 2019. Gossip and reputation in social networks. In Oxford handbook on gossip and reputation (eds Giardini F, Wittek RPM), pp. 435-457. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 191.Labun A, Wittek R, Steglich C. 2016. The co-evolution of power and friendship networks in an organization. Netw. Sci. 4, 364-384. ( 10.1017/nws.2016.7) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 192.Van de Bunt GG, Wittek RP, de Klepper MC. 2005. The evolution of intra-organizational trust networks: the case of a German paper factory: an empirical test of six trust mechanisms. Int. Sociol. 20, 339-369. ( 10.1177/0268580905055480) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 193.Kilduff M, Lee JW. 2020. The integration of people and networks. Annu. Rev. Organ. Psychol. Organ. Behav. 7, 155-179. ( 10.1146/annurev-orgpsych-012119-045357) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 194.Lindenberg S. 2015. Groups, sociology of. In International encyclopedia of the social & behavioral sciences, 2nd edn (ed. JD Wright), pp. 434-440. Oxford, UK: Elsevier. [Google Scholar]
  • 195.Freeman LC. 1992. The sociological concept of ‘group’: an empirical test of two models. Am. J. Sociol. 98, 152-166. ( 10.1086/229972) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 196.Zeggelink EP, Stokman FN, Van De Bunt GG. 1996. The emergence of groups in the evolution of friendship networks. J. Math. Sociol. 21, 29-55. ( 10.1080/0022250X.1996.9990173) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 197.Moody J, White DR. 2003. Structural cohesion and embeddedness: a hierarchical concept of social groups. Am. Sociol. Rev. 68, 103-127. ( 10.2307/3088904) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 198.Newman ME. 2006. Modularity and community structure in networks. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 103, 8577-8582. ( 10.1073/pnas.0601602103) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 199.Rusch H. 2014. The evolutionary interplay of intergroup conflict and altruism in humans: a review of parochial altruism theory and prospects for its extension. Proc. R. Soc. B 281, 20141539. ( 10.1098/rspb.2014.1539) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 200.Balliet D, Wu J, De Dreu CK. 2014. Ingroup favoritism in cooperation: a meta-analysis. Psychol. Bull. 140, 1556. ( 10.1037/a0037737) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 201.Lane T. 2016. Discrimination in the laboratory: a meta-analysis of economics experiments. Eur. Econ. Rev. 90, 375-402. ( 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.11.011) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 202.De Dreu CK, Balliet D, Halevy N. 2014. Parochial cooperation in humans: forms and functions of self-sacrifice in intergroup conflict. Adv. Motiv. Sci. 1, 1-47. ( 10.1016/bs.adms.2014.08.001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 203.Mifune N, Hashimoto H, Yamagishi T. 2010. Altruism toward in-group members as a reputation mechanism. Evol. Hum. Behav. 31, 109-117. ( 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2009.09.004) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 204.Tajfel H, Turner JC. 1986. The social identity theory of intergroup behavior. In The social psychology of intergroup relations (eds Worchel S, Austin WG). Chicago, IL: Nelson-Hall. [Google Scholar]
  • 205.Turner JC, Brown RJ, Tajfel H. 1979. Social comparison and group interest in ingroup favouritism. Eur. J. Soc. Psychol. 9, 187-204. ( 10.1002/ejsp.2420090207) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 206.Turner JC, Hogg MA, Oakes PJ, Reicher SD, Wetherell MS. 1987. Rediscovering the social group: a self-categorization theory. Oxford, UK: Basil Blackwell. [Google Scholar]
  • 207.Yamagishi T, Jin N, Kiyonari T. 1999. Bounded generalized reciprocity: ingroup boasting and ingroup favoritism. Adv. Group Process. 16, 161-197. [Google Scholar]
  • 208.Böhm R, Rusch H, Baron J. 2020. The psychology of intergroup conflict: a review of theories and measures. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 178, 947-962. ( 10.1016/j.jebo.2018.01.020) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 209.Romano A, Balliet D, Yamagishi T, Liu JH. 2017. Parochial trust and cooperation across 17 societies. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 114, 12 702-12 707. ( 10.1073/pnas.1712921114) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 210.Romano A, Balliet D, Wu J. 2017. Unbounded indirect reciprocity: is reputation-based cooperation bounded by group membership? J. Exp. Social Psychol. 71, 59-67. ( 10.1016/j.jesp.2017.02.008) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 211.Pisor AC, Gurven M. 2016. Risk buffering and resource access shape valuation of out-group strangers. Scient. Rep. 6, 30435. ( 10.1038/srep30435) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 212.Baranski B, et al. 2006. The impact of group reputation in multiagent environments. In 2006 IEEE Int. Conf. Evolutionary Computation, 16–21 July 2006, Vancouver, BC, Canada, pp. 1224-1231. IEEE. ( 10.1109/CEC.2006.1688449) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 213.Masuda N. 2012. Ingroup favoritism and intergroup cooperation under indirect reciprocity based on group reputation. J. Theor. Biol. 311, 8-18. ( 10.1016/j.jtbi.2012.07.002) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 214.Bedewi W, Whitaker RM, Colombo GB, Allen SM, Dunham Y. 2020. The implications of shared identity on indirect reciprocity. J. Inform. Telecommun. 4, 405-424. ( 10.1080/24751839.2020.1741858) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 215.Stadtfeld C, Takács K, Vörös A. 2020. The emergence and stability of groups in social networks. Social Netw. 60, 129-145. ( 10.1016/j.socnet.2019.10.008) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 216.Jensen GG, Tischel F, Bornholdt S. 2019. Discrimination emerging through spontaneous symmetry breaking in a spatial prisoner's dilemma model with multiple labels. Phys. Rev. E 100, 062302. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.100.062302) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 217.Apicella CL, Marlowe FW, Fowler JH, Christakis NA. 2012. Social networks and cooperation in hunter-gatherers. Nature 481, 497-501. ( 10.1038/nature10736) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 218.Smith KM, Larroucau T, Mabulla IA, Apicella CL. 2018. Hunter-gatherers maintain assortativity in cooperation despite high levels of residential change and mixing. Curr. Biol. 28, 3152-3157. ( 10.1016/j.cub.2018.07.064) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 219.Ehlert A, Kindschi M, Algesheimer R, Rauhut H. 2020. Human social preferences cluster and spread in the field. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 117, 22 787-22 792. ( 10.1073/pnas.2000824117) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 220.Hauert C, De Monte S, Hofbauer J, Sigmund K. 2002. Volunteering as red queen mechanism for cooperation in public goods games. Science 296, 1129-1132. ( 10.1126/science.1070582) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 221.Barclay P. 2004. Trustworthiness and competitive altruism can also solve the "tragedy of the commons". Evol. Hum. Behav. 25, 209-220. ( 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2004.04.002) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 222.Hardy CL, Van Vugt M. 2006. Nice guys finish first: the competitive altruism hypothesis. Pers. Social Psychol. Bull. 32, 1402-1413. ( 10.1177/0146167206291006) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 223.Van Vugt M, Roberts G, Hardy C. 2007. Competitive altruism: development of reputation-based cooperation in groups. In Handbook of evolutionary psychology (eds R Dunbar, L Barrett), pp. 531-540. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 224.Kuran T. 1997. Private truths, public lies. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 225.Centola D, Willer R, Macy M. 2005. The emperor's dilemma: a computational model of self-enforcing norms. Am. J. Sociol. 110, 1009-1040. ( 10.1086/427321) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 226.Gurven M, Allen-Arave W, Hill K, Hurtado M. 2000. "It's a wonderful life": signaling generosity among the Ache of Paraguay. Evol. Hum. Behav. 21, 263-282. ( 10.1016/S1090-5138(00)00032-5) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 227.Wiessner P. 2002. Hunting, healing, and hxaro exchange: a long-term perspective on !Kung (Ju/'hoansi) large-game hunting. Evol. Hum. Behav. 23, 407-436. ( 10.1016/S1090-5138(02)00096-X) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 228.Smith EA. 2004. Why do good hunters have higher reproductive success? Hum. Nat. 15, 343-364. ( 10.1007/s12110-004-1013-9) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 229.Ziker J, Schnegg M. 2005. Food sharing at meals. Hum. Nat. 16, 178-210. ( 10.1007/s12110-005-1003-6) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 230.Nolin DA. 2010. Food-sharing networks in Lamalera, Indonesia. Hum. Nat. 21, 243-268. ( 10.1007/s12110-010-9091-3) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 231.Nolin DA. 2012. Food-sharing networks in Lamalera, Indonesia: status, sharing, and signaling. Evol. Hum. Behav. 33, 334-345. ( 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2011.11.003) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 232.Ready E, Power EA. 2018. Why wage earners hunt: food sharing, social structure, and influence in an Arctic mixed economy. Curr. Anthropol. 59, 74-97. ( 10.1086/696018) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 233.Barclay P. 2010. Altruism as a courtship display: some effects of third-party generosity on audience perceptions. Br. J. Psychol. 101, 123-135. ( 10.1348/000712609X435733) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 234.Wu J, Balliet D, Van Lange PA. 2016. Reputation management: why and how gossip enhances generosity. Evol. Hum. Behav. 37, 193-201. ( 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2015.11.001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 235.Lyle HF, Smith EA. 2014. The reputational and social network benefits of prosociality in an Andean community. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 111, 4820-4825. ( 10.1073/pnas.1318372111) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 236.Bliege Bird R, Ready E, Power EA. 2018. The social significance of subtle signals. Nat. Hum. Behav. 2, 452-457. ( 10.1038/s41562-018-0298-3) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 237.Smaldino PE. 2019. Social identity and cooperation in cultural evolution. Behav. Processes 161, 108-116. ( 10.1016/j.beproc.2017.11.015) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 238.Atkisson C, Górski PJ, Jackson MO, Hołyst JA, D'Souza RM. 2020. Why understanding multiplex social network structuring processes will help us better understand the evolution of human behavior. Evol. Anthropol. 29, 102-107. ( 10.1002/evan.21850) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 239.Baldassarri D, Grossman G. 2011. Centralized sanctioning and legitimate authority promote cooperation in humans. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 108, 11 023-11 027. ( 10.1073/pnas.1105456108) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 240.Baldassarri D. 2015. Cooperative networks: altruism, group solidarity, reciprocity, and sanctioning in Ugandan producer organizations. Am. J. Sociol. 121, 355-395. ( 10.1086/682418) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 241.Fehr E, Schurtenberger I. 2018. Normative foundations of human cooperation. Nat. Hum. Behav. 2, 458-468. ( 10.1038/s41562-018-0385-5) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 242.Diekmann A, Przepiorka W. 2019. Trust and reputation in markets. In The Oxford handbook of gossip and reputation (eds Giardini F, Wittek RPM). Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 243.Gürerk Ö, Irlenbusch B, Rockenbach B. 2006. The competitive advantage of sanctioning institutions. Science 312, 108-111. ( 10.1126/science.1123633) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 244.Greif A. 1989. Reputation and coalitions in medieval trade: evidence on the Maghribi traders. J. Econ. Hist. 49, 857-882. ( 10.1017/S0022050700009475) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 245.Greif A. 2005. Commitment, coercion, and markets: the nature and dynamics of institutions supporting exchange. In Handbook of new institutional economics (eds Ménard C, Shirley M), pp. 727-786. Boston, MA: Springer. [Google Scholar]
  • 246.Milgrom PR, North DC, Weingast BR. 1990. The role of institutions in the revival of trade: the law merchant, private judges, and the champagne fairs. Econ. Polit. 2, 1-23. ( 10.1111/j.1468-0343.1990.tb00020.x) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 247.Temin P. 2013. The Roman market economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 248.Macfarlan SJ, Lyle HF. 2015. Multiple reputation domains and cooperative behaviour in two Latin American communities. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 370, 20150009. ( 10.1098/rstb.2015.0009) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 249.Balliet D, Li NP, Macfarlan SJ, Van Vugt M. 2011. Sex differences in cooperation: a meta-analytic review of social dilemmas. Psychol. Bull. 137, 881-909. ( 10.1037/a0025354) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 250.Rucas SL, Gurven M, Kaplan H, Winking J. 2010. The social strategy game. Hum. Nat. 21, 1-18. ( 10.1007/s12110-010-9079-z) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 251.Herrmann E, Engelmann JM, Tomasello M. 2019. Children engage in competitive altruism. J. Exp. Child Psychol. 179, 176-189. ( 10.1016/j.jecp.2018.11.008) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 252.Stevens JR, Woike JK, Schooler LJ, Lindner S, Pachur T. 2018. Social contact patterns can buffer costs of forgetting in the evolution of cooperation. Proc. R. Soc. B 285, 20180407. ( 10.1098/rspb.2018.0407) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 253.Winke T, Stevens JR. 2017. Is cooperative memory special? The role of costly errors, context, and social network size when remembering cooperative actions. Front. Robot. AI 4, 52. ( 10.3389/frobt.2017.00052) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 254.Conte R, Paolucci M. 2002. Reputation in artificial societies: social beliefs for social order. Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers. [Google Scholar]
  • 255.Bachrach Y, Parnes A, Procaccia AD, Rosenschein JS. 2009. Gossip-based aggregation of trust in decentralized reputation systems. Auton. Agents Multi-Agent Syst. 19, 153-172. ( 10.1007/s10458-008-9073-6) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 256.Smith ER. 2014. Evil acts and malicious gossip: a multiagent model of the effects of gossip in socially distributed person perception. Pers. Social Psychol. Rev. 18, 311-325. ( 10.1177/1088868314530515) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 257.Rapoport A, Diekmann A, Franzen A. 1995. Experiments with social traps IV: reputation effects in the evolution of cooperation. Rational. Soc. 7, 431-441. ( 10.1177/104346319500700407) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 258.Van Vugt M, Hardy CL. 2010. Cooperation for reputation: wasteful contributions as costly signals in public goods. Group Process. Intergroup Relat. 13, 101-111. ( 10.1177/1368430209342258) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 259.Pisor AC, Gervais MM, Purzycki BG, Ross CT. 2020. Preferences and constraints: the value of economic games for studying human behaviour. R. Soc. Open Sci. 7, 192090. ( 10.1098/rsos.192090) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 260.Hogg T, Adamic L. 2004. Enhancing reputation mechanisms via online social networks. EC '04: Proc. 5th ACM Conf. Electronic Commerce, New York, 17–20 May 2004, pp. 236-237. New York, NY: Association for Computing Machinery. ( 10.1145/988772.988811) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 261.Diekmann A, Jann B, Przepiorka W, Wehrli S. 2014. Reputation formation and the evolution of cooperation in anonymous online markets. Am. Sociol. Rev. 79, 65-85. ( 10.1177/0003122413512316) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 262.Przepiorka W, Norbutas L, Corten R. 2017. Order without law: reputation promotes cooperation in a cryptomarket for illegal drugs. Eur. Sociol. Rev. 33, 752-764. ( 10.1093/esr/jcx072) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 263.Snijders C, Matzat U. 2019. Online reputation systems. In The Oxford handbook of gossip and reputation (eds Giardini F, Wittek RPM), pp. 479-495. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 264.Al-Yazidi S, Berri J, Al-Qurishi M, Al-Alrubaian M. 2020. Measuring reputation and influence in online social networks: a systematic literature review. IEEE Access 8, 105 824-105 851. ( 10.1109/ACCESS.2020.2999033) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 265.Lazega E. 2001. The collegial phenomenon: the social mechanisms of cooperation among peers in a corporate law partnership. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  • 266.Power EA. 2017. Social support networks and religiosity in rural South India. Nat. Hum. Behav. 1, 0057. ( 10.1038/s41562-017-0057) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 267.Power EA, Ready E. 2018. Building bigness: reputation, prominence, and social capital in rural South India. Am. Anthropol. 120, 444-459. ( 10.1111/aman.13100) [DOI] [Google Scholar]

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Data Availability Statement

This article has no additional data.


Articles from Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences are provided here courtesy of The Royal Society

RESOURCES