Skip to main content
Bulletin of the World Health Organization logoLink to Bulletin of the World Health Organization
. 2021 Sep 30;99(11):819–827. doi: 10.2471/BLT.20.285227

Promotion of behavioural change for health in a heterogeneous population

Promotion du changement comportemental en matière de santé au sein d'une population hétérogène

Promoción del cambio de comportamiento en pro de la salud en una población heterogénea

تعزيز التغيير السلوكي من أجل الصحة في مجموعة غير متجانسة من السكان

促进异质群体的健康行为变化

Содействие изменению поведения в интересах здоровья неоднородной популяции населения

Robin Schimmelpfennig a,, Sonja Vogt a, Sönke Ehret a, Charles Efferson a
PMCID: PMC8542272  PMID: 34737474

Abstract

Public health policy often involves implementing cost-efficient, large-scale interventions. When mandating or forbidding a specific behaviour is not permissible, public health professionals may draw on behaviour change interventions to achieve socially beneficial policy objectives. Interventions can have two main effects: (i) a direct effect on people initially targeted by the intervention; and (ii) an indirect effect mediated by social influence and by the observation of other people’s behaviour. However, people’s attitudes and beliefs can differ markedly throughout the population, with the result that these two effects can interact to produce unexpected, unhelpful and counterintuitive consequences. Public health professionals need to understand this interaction better. This paper illustrates the key principles of this interaction by examining two important areas of public health policy: tobacco smoking and vaccination. The example of antismoking campaigns shows when and how public health professionals can amplify the effects of a behaviour change intervention by taking advantage of the indirect pathway. The example of vaccination campaigns illustrates how underlying incentive structures, particularly anticoordination incentives, can interfere with the indirect effect of an intervention and stall efforts to scale up its implementation. Recommendations are presented on how public health professionals can maximize the total effect of behaviour change interventions in heterogeneous populations based on these concepts and examples.

Introduction

Public health policy objectives often conflict with local culture.13 Thus, to avoid a backlash when trying to change people’s behaviour, policy-makers may often resist policies that forbid or mandate a specific behaviour. They may instead work with public health professionals to design interventions aimed at changing behaviour that do not restrict freedom of choice.4 However, for various reasons, such as budgetary or infrastructure constraints, it is often impractical to ensure that the entire population is exposed to such interventions. One workaround is to tap into social influence mechanisms. Social influence can help bring about behaviour change in individuals in the population who cannot be reached by the intervention. When individuals have an interest in behaving like those around them, the behaviour change among those initially exposed to the intervention can spill over to influence those not exposed.47 Consequently, the potential of social influence and behavioural spillover to amplify the impact of policy interventions in this way has received much attention in various areas of public health, such as scaling up vaccine delivery,8,9 reducing the prevalence of female genital mutilation,1 combating gun violence and smoking,10,11 and challenging norms on sex-selective abortion.2,12

When socially beneficial interventions are optimally designed and implemented, behavioural spillover can dramatically amplify their effects in a cost-efficient way. The mechanisms that drive spillover, however, will be subtle and will vary according to culture, the group targeted by the intervention and the behaviour of interest.13,14 Here we examine two subtle mechanisms that may help public health professionals maximize behaviour change in support of public health objectives.15,16 First, we draw on the results of empirically informed models to show how ordinary forms of heterogeneity in attitudes, beliefs, and behaviours between individuals can determine which segment of the population should be targeted by an intervention. Second, we examine how behavioural spillover can be critically influenced by the interaction between two common forms of heterogeneity: (i) the variation in when people respond to others changing their behaviour (i.e. the variation in people’s tendency to make a socially beneficial behavioural choice based on how common this choice is among their peers); and (ii) the variation in perceptions of the costs and benefits associated with a behavioural choice.

Here we consider antismoking and vaccination campaigns to illustrate how these two common forms of heterogeneity can interact to affect behaviour change in unexpected ways. Current discussions of social influence in behavioural public health policy do not typically account for these important issues.8,9,17 We also provide recommendations on managing the trade-offs involved in attempting to change behaviour when people have differing attitudes and beliefs but still influence each other.

Behavioural spillover

To conceptualize how social influence can affect behavioural spillover, consider the example of a public health professional who wants to maximize behavioural change among smokers. The professional will have an intervention in mind, say a media campaign to persuade people to stop smoking,11,18,19 which could target a subset of the population. We can split the total effect of the campaign into a direct effect and an indirect effect (Fig. 1). Some people in the population will change their behaviour after being directly exposed to the media campaign (i.e. the direct effect). The remainder will not have changed their behaviour, either because they did not respond after being exposed to the campaign or because they were not exposed to it. Crucially, this second part of the population may still change their behaviour by stopping smoking after observing others doing so. Behaviour change brought about by social influence in this way is the indirect effect of the intervention. Research has shown that, under some conditions, the indirect effect can be more pronounced than the initial direct effect.5,7

Fig. 1.

Direct and indirect effects of an antismoking campaign

Note: The total effect of a campaign is the sum of its direct and indirect effects.

Fig. 1

Individuals differ from each other for many reasons. For example, they may differ in their tendency to respond to an intervention,20 which will shape the direct effect of the intervention. A lifelong smoker who has never considered stopping will be much less likely to be persuaded by a media campaign than someone who just started smoking. Alternatively, individuals may differ in when they respond to social information, which will influence the indirect effect of the intervention. Some people may only stop smoking after observing 50% of people they know doing so, others may change their behaviour after only 20% have stopped and others only when 85% have done so. Some public health professionals may regard such mundane forms of heterogeneity in attitudes and preferences as secondary details, but they are not. The key question is how they interact to shape behavioural spillover and, by extension, influence the total effect of the behaviour change intervention. The answer to this question involves resolving the fundamental trade-off between maximizing the direct or indirect effect of an intervention.

Targeting amenable or resistant individuals

In our example on modifying smoking behaviour, the public health professional must maximize the total effect of the policy initiative by taking advantage of social influence and associated behavioural spillover. Accordingly, a basic decision needs to be made. Assuming the whole population cannot be reached (e.g. due to budgetary constraints), the health professional must decide how many people should be targeted by the media campaign and who these people should be. Given that everyone in the target population smokes, intuition might suggest prioritizing those more amenable to change. In fact, targeting amenable individuals has often been explicitly or implicitly recommended.1,21,22 Moreover, even if individuals amenable to change are not specifically targeted, they may self-select to be exposed to the intervention precisely because they find the policy objective attractive. In essence, smokers uncomfortable with their behaviour may seek out information encouraging them to stop smoking, which will increase the direct effect of antismoking media campaigns.

The intuitive appeal of targeting amenable individuals is unreliable because the heterogeneity in attitudes and preferences throughout the population creates a fundamental but poorly understood trade-off for public health professionals.13 To illustrate the nature of this trade-off, consider two extreme strategies: (i) targeting the segment of the population most amenable to change and most likely to respond to the intervention; and (ii) targeting the most resistant segment. There is also the intermediate case of targeting randomly selected individuals. The main characteristics of this trade-off are summarized in Table 1. The best way to resolve the trade-off, and thus maximize the total effect of an intervention, will depend both on how common different attitudes are in the population and on how people respond to the intervention and to other people’s behaviour change.

Table 1. The trade-off between targeting amenable or resistant individuals with behavioural interventions.

Subset of population targeted by the intervention Effect of the intervention
Direct effect Indirect effect
Amenable individuals
Targeting those most likely to change behaviour maximizes the direct effect of the intervention
Targeting those most likely to change behaviour means relying on the indirect effect of the intervention to influence those least likely to change. For a given magnitude of direct effect, targeting those most likely to change minimizes the indirect effect of the intervention and, by extension, behavioural spillover
Resistant individuals
Targeting those least likely to change behaviour minimizes the direct effect of the intervention
For a given magnitude of direct effect, targeting those least likely to change behaviour maximizes the indirect effect of the intervention because those most likely to change will be affected indirectly but were not directly targeted
Randomly selected individuals The size of the direct effect will be intermediate between the effects of targeting either amenable or resistant individuals The size of the indirect effect will be intermediate between the effects of targeting either amenable or resistant individuals

To gain an insight into which strategy may be preferable in a particular situation, we have adapted Efferson et al.’s empirically grounded modelling work.13 An individual’s pre-existing attitudes will shape both how likely the individual is to respond to exposure to a media campaign and how many other people have to stop smoking before the decision is made to do so. Pre-existing attitudes in a population vary on a continuous scale from relatively amenable to change to resistant to change. Furthermore, attitudes are not fixed but can evolve, for example, after being exposed to a public health professional’s media campaign.

Fig. 2 and Fig. 3 illustrate how the direct and total effects of a behavioural intervention (e.g. an antismoking campaign) can change as the proportion of the population targeted increases and as different types of individual are targeted in two contexts: where the probability of change is high or low, respectively. When the probability of responding to an intervention by changing behaviour is high for everyone except those most resistant to change (Fig. 2), all individuals but the most resistant will probably change their behaviour and stop smoking if exposed to the media campaign. In this case, targeting individuals amenable to change would yield only a small increase in the direct effect of the intervention and targeting either randomly selected people or resistant people would yield even smaller increases. Surprisingly, behavioural spillover and, by extension, the total effect of the intervention are dramatically larger when either randomly selected or resistant people are targeted than when amenable people are targeted. In this situation, the indirect effect dominates the direct effect and targeting amenable people minimizes the indirect effect. Consequently, the public health professional can best resolve the trade-off by choosing a campaign that targets randomly selected or resistant individuals. Moreover, the intervention can be relatively small, so long as people most amenable to change are not targeted. For instance, targeting only 20% of the population can trigger a large behavioural spillover. This reasoning may at first seem counterintuitive but, when everyone except the most resistant is likely to respond to the intervention, the best way to maximize behaviour change is to avoid targeting those most amenable to change. The direct effect of the intervention on randomly selected or resistant individuals sparks an indirect effect among those amenable to change, which then leads to further indirect effects as more and more people stop smoking in a cascade of behaviour change.

Fig. 2.

Direct and total effects of a behavioural change intervention with the assumption that the probability of change is high except in people most resistant to change, by target group

Note: The total effect of the intervention is the sum of its direct and indirect effects. People’s responses to the intervention are affected by their pre-existing attitudes, specifically by how resistant or amenable they are to the new behaviour. For this figure, it was assumed that the probability of behaviour change on exposure to the intervention was relatively high for all but the most resistant. The target group comprises the type of individuals who would initially be targeted by the intervention. For example, if the target size is 50% and the target group comprises resistant individuals, the 50% of the population with the highest resistance (based on their attitudes) is targeted. More details are available from the data repository.23

Fig. 2

Fig. 3.

Direct and total effects of a behavioural change intervention with the assumption that the probability of change is low except in people most amenable to change, by target group

Note: The total effect of the intervention is the sum of its direct and indirect effects. People’s responses to the intervention are affected by their pre-existing attitudes, specifically by how resistant or amenable they are to the new behaviour. For this figure, it was assumed that the probability of behaviour change on exposure to the intervention was relatively low for all but the most amenable. The target group comprises the type of individuals who would initially be targeted by the intervention. For example, if the target size is 50% and the target group comprises resistant individuals, the 50% of the population with the highest resistance (based on their attitudes) is targeted. More details are available from the data repository.23

Fig. 3

When the probability of responding to an intervention by changing behaviour is very low for everyone except those most amenable to change (Fig. 3), people already on the cusp of stopping smoking are likely to respond to the media campaign whereas most others are unlikely to respond. In this situation, targeting those amenable to change maximizes both the direct and total effects of the intervention and the public health professional can resolve the basic trade-off by choosing a campaign that targets people amenable to change. However, in this scenario the professional faces a larger challenge than determining how to resolve the trade-off between increasing the direct or indirect effect of the intervention. The situation is generally unfavourable for behaviour change and only people ready to stop smoking are likely to respond to the intervention. Therefore, although targeting people amenable to change results in more behaviour change than targeting randomly selected or resistant individuals, the primary problem is that the intervention is inadequate. The best approach, then, is to try to improve the intervention, which in turn may alter the best way to resolve the trade-off between its direct and indirect effects.

Faced with the typical situation in public health in which people have different attitudes and beliefs and where an intervention is likely to reach only a limited number, public health professionals must make an informed decision on who to target. The modelling results reported here show that the behaviour change achievable is strongly influenced by the heterogeneity of attitudes and beliefs common in many populations. However, professionals may not always be able to identify or measure that heterogeneity. For example, attitudes may not be observable and people may be unwilling to share their preferences openly when asked.24 In addition, budgetary and time constraints may make it impossible or impractical to conduct a representative survey of attitudes and preferences. In this context, targeting randomly selected individuals with the intervention can be a comparably safe bet because, in terms of the intervention’s effectiveness, targeting randomly selected individuals falls between targeting the extremes of amenable or resistant individuals, thereby avoiding the potential weaknesses of both (Fig. 2 and Fig. 3). The public health professional’s only task in such situations is to avoid biased selection. More detailed information on how direct and indirect effects are influenced by the probability of changing behaviour is available from the data repository.23

Conformity and anticoordination incentives

The different approaches to changing smoking behaviour discussed above assume that the interventions involve incentives for people to coordinate their behaviour.25,26 In this setting and many similar situations which involve coordination incentives, the influences of conformity and coordination incentives act in the same direction. In other situations, however, conformity and anticoordination incentives can act as countervailing influences.

A review of the literature on vaccination behaviour illustrates this opposition between conformity and anticoordination incentives. A considerable amount of research has demonstrated the importance of social norms and conformity for vaccine delivery.9,2731 Furthermore, conformity has been reported to be relatively efficient in supporting vaccination campaigns when coupled with an initial focus on well connected individuals.32 Public health professionals generally aim to increase the proportion of vaccinated individuals in the population beyond the threshold for herd immunity and social influence may support them in this endeavour. However, once a certain proportion has been vaccinated, anticoordination incentives can favour opting out of vaccination.30 For example, the perceived value of vaccination may decrease as the number of people vaccinated increases (Fig. 4) because the risk an unvaccinated person will catch the disease declines as vaccination becomes more widespread.30 In this context, general incentives for vaccination involve some pressure to do what others are not doing. With antismoking campaigns in contrast, the incentives involve persuading people to do what others are doing. Vaccination, then, can present people with an anticoordination incentive: a single unvaccinated person in a population in which everyone else has been vaccinated has little reason to get the vaccine. The same is probably true for two or even a dozen unvaccinated individuals. More detailed information on coordination incentives is available from the data repository.33

Fig. 4.

Population vaccination rate and the perceived value of vaccination in an anticoordination setting

Note: The perceived value of vaccination may decrease as the number of people vaccinated increases while the costs of vaccination remain unchanged. The benefit of vaccination can approach zero when nearly everyone in the population is vaccinated because the risk an unvaccinated individual will catch the disease is small. In contrast, the perceived value of not getting vaccinated increases as more people get vaccinated (i.e. the anticoordination incentive). The end result is a stable equilibrium with some people choosing vaccination and others not. An intervention can shift the equilibrium (arrow) by providing incentives, information or behavioural nudges or reducing costs and concerns about side-effects. More information about the intersection of value functions is available from the data repository.33

Fig. 4

The question for public health professionals is, what proportion of the population must be vaccinated for the incentive to switch from favouring vaccination to favouring the decision not to vaccinate? The answer depends on how the net value of the vaccine varies with the number of people vaccinated. The perceived cost of contracting the disease when unvaccinated must be balanced against the possible fixed costs of vaccination associated, for example, with possible allergic reactions and the expense of, and time needed to go for, vaccination. In addition, there is the fear fanned by misinformation and antivaccine movements.34 Once enough people have been vaccinated to ensure that, for the unvaccinated, the perceived value of not getting the vaccine exceeds the perceived value of vaccination, the proportion of people vaccinated will reach a stable equilibrium. Put differently, unvaccinated people are reaping the benefit of the reduced infection risk associated with herd immunity without paying the cost of vaccination.35 However, if the equilibrium point is below the threshold for herd immunity, public health professionals will need to design interventions that increase the vaccination rate to a point above the herd immunity threshold (Fig. 4). Regardless of the precise benefits and costs of being vaccinated or not, anticoordination incentives, unlike coordination incentives, do not amplify the effects of an intervention via spillover behaviour. Indeed, they do exactly the opposite by encouraging some people not to adopt the health professional’s preferred behaviour.

To support the policy objective of achieving a vaccination rate above the threshold for herd immunity, public health professionals could use different strategies to counter anticoordination incentives. First, they can make vaccination rewarding: reduce the monetary and time cost of vaccination or provide financial incentives, for example, in the form of cash transfers, lottery tickets, vouchers or material goods.3639 Second, they can make vaccination appealing: public health professionals should communicate effectively about the low risk of vaccination side-effects and the health benefits of the vaccine and counter people’s fears, which may originate from misinformation.34,35 Third, they can make vaccination easy: use behavioural nudges, for example in the form of reminders, prompts or default options. This could help to reduce the perceived time costs of vaccination and overcome inertia and a lack of motivation in people who are generally open to being vaccinated.37,40

A combination of these strategies is recommended,37 especially when mandates are not permissible or practical.41 However, not all strategies will have the desired effect in all settings. Direct financial incentives, for example, may reduce the overall level of vaccination through so-called crowding out:4245 financial incentives could lessen the social motivation of some people who would get vaccinated primarily to protect vulnerable others. Offering payment can turn social behaviour into market behaviour, possibly leading people to abstain. Whatever the best solution is in a specific setting, public health professionals should focus on countering anticoordination incentives to promote large-scale vaccination uptake beyond the threshold of herd immunity.

Conclusion

When public health professionals implement behavioural change interventions that rely on social influence, they can expect results ranging from the spectacular to the negligible. Although specific mechanisms such as conformity and coordination incentives can dramatically amplify the beneficial effects of a policy initiative, the details are crucial and the policy’s success is influenced by several poorly understood and subtle mechanisms.45,46 Practical recommendations for maximizing behaviour change based on the concepts discussed are summarized in Box 1.

Box 1. Practical recommendations for maximizing behaviour change.

1. Are the resources and infrastructure available to reach the whole population with a behaviour change intervention?

  • Yes: behavioural spillover can be cost-efficient but may not be necessary to achieve the policy goal.

  • No: behavioural spillover might help to indirectly reach those who cannot be reached directly (the following steps explain how this could be achieved).

2. Is detailed information available about the heterogeneity of attitudes in the population?

  • Yes: knowledge about attitudes can be used to maximize the total effect of the intervention, not just the direct effect (the following step explains how this could be achieved).

  • No: there are different solutions: (i) develop the methods and capacity needed to assess existing attitudes; (ii) use available sociodemographic data as a proxy for attitudes;47 or (iii) choose to target randomly selected individuals with the intervention because this a relatively safe option that will avoid the pitfalls of designing an intervention to target either amenable or resistant individuals when the predominant attitudes of the population are unknown.

3. How effective is the intervention in changing behaviour among different individuals in the population?

  • If it is effective among everyone except the most resistant, it is advisable to avoid targeting the most amenable.

  • If it is effective among only the most amenable, the campaign is not particularly effective overall. Solutions: (i) improve the effectiveness of the intervention; (ii) selectively target only the small amenable population using low-cost measures; (iii) directly target a large subset of the population with an intervention (in many cases, this will be much more than 50%); or (iv) design an intervention that decouples group identity from the target behaviour if resistance to the behaviour change is related to deeply rooted group identities or traditions.13

4. Does the target behaviour involve coordination incentives (i.e. individuals will prefer behaviour A to behaviour B when everyone else is exhibiting behaviour A and will prefer behaviour B to behaviour A when nobody else is exhibiting behaviour A)?

  • Yes: public health professionals should focus on triggering behavioural spillover because conformity and coordination incentives will both support the policy objective once the desired behaviour is sufficiently common.

  • No: it is possible that anticoordination incentives may be encouraging people to do the opposite to others. These can be attenuated by: (i) increasing the value of the target behaviour (e.g. through financial incentives); (ii) providing information; or (iii) employing behavioural nudges.

5. Evaluating the impact of the behavioural change intervention

  • Even if an intervention seems unsuccessful at first, it may create large-scale behavioural change through spillover. Consequently, the effect of the intervention should be evaluated in a sample of people who were not targeted. Repeated evaluations are advisable as a single evaluation immediately after the intervention ends could miss indirect effects that unfold over time.

We hope our observations will contribute to the field of public health by illustrating how the possible effects of behavioural change interventions can vary according to the people’s different attitudes and beliefs. As a result, these interventions can have unexpected, unhelpful and counterintuitive consequences. Ideally, public health professionals should gain a better understanding of both the direct and indirect effects of their interventions by assessing the different attitudes and beliefs among people in their target population. The strategies we describe could help public health professionals take their first steps towards effectively managing behavioural spillover when designing public health interventions.

Acknowledgements

We thank Surabhi Rajaram.

Competing interests:

None declared.

References

  • 1.Cloward K. When norms collide: local responses to activism against female genital mutilation and early marriage. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2016. 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780190274917.001.0001 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 2.Platteau JP, Camilotti G, Auriol E. Eradicating women-hurting customs. What role for social engineering? In: Anderson S, Beaman LA, Platteau JP, editors. Towards gender equity in development. 1st ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2018. [Google Scholar]
  • 3.Shell-Duncan B, Hernlund Y. Female “circumcision” in Africa: culture, controversy, and change. Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publishers; 2000. [Google Scholar]
  • 4.World development report 2015: mind, society, and behavior. Washington, DC: World Bank Group; 2015. Available from: https://www.worldbank.org/en/publication/wdr2015 [cited 2021 Dec 13].
  • 5.Andreoni J, Nikiforakis N, Siegenthaler S. Predicting social tipping and norm change in controlled experiments. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA. 2021. April 20;118(16):e2014893118. 10.1073/pnas.2014893118 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6.Dolan P, Hallsworth M, Halpern D, King D, Metcalfe R, Vlaev I. Influencing behaviour: the mindspace way. J Econ Psychol. 2012;33(1):264–77. 10.1016/j.joep.2011.10.009 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 7.Nyborg K, Anderies JM, Dannenberg A, Lindahl T, Schill C, Schlüter M, et al. Social norms as solutions. Science. 2016. October 7;354(6308):42–3. 10.1126/science.aaf8317 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 8.Brewer NT, Chapman GB, Rothman AJ, Leask J, Kempe A. Increasing vaccination: putting psychological science into action. Psychol Sci Public Interest. 2017. December;18(3):149–207. 10.1177/1529100618760521 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 9.Behavioural considerations for acceptance and uptake of COVID-19 vaccines. WHO Technical Advisory Group on Behavioural Insights and Sciences for Health, meeting report, 15 October 2020.Geneva: World Health Organization; 2020. Available from: https://apps.who.int/iris/bitstream/handle/10665/337335/9789240016927-eng.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y [cited 2020 Dec 13].
  • 10.Tracy M, Braga AA, Papachristos AV. The transmission of gun and other weapon-involved violence within social networks. Epidemiol Rev. 2016;38(1):70–86. 10.1093/epirev/mxv009 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 11.Christakis NA, Fowler JH. The collective dynamics of smoking in a large social network. N Engl J Med. 2008. May 22;358(21):2249–58. 10.1056/NEJMsa0706154 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Schief M, Vogt S, Efferson C. Investigating the structure of son bias in Armenia with novel measures of individual preferences. Rochester: SSRN eLibrary; 2019. 10.2139/ssrn.3469644 10.2139/ssrn.3469644 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
  • 13.Efferson C, Vogt S, Fehr E. The promise and the peril of using social influence to reverse harmful traditions. Nat Hum Behav. 2020. January;4(1):55–68. 10.1038/s41562-019-0768-2 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14.Muthukrishna M. Cultural evolutionary public policy. Nat Hum Behav. 2020. January;4(1):12–3. 10.1038/s41562-019-0780-6 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 15.Haines A, Kuruvilla S, Borchert M. Bridging the implementation gap between knowledge and action for health. Bull World Health Organ. 2004. October;82(10):724–31, discussion 732. [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 16.Johri M, Pérez MC, Arsenault C, Sharma JK, Pai NP, Pahwa S, et al. Strategies to increase the demand for childhood vaccination in low- and middle-income countries: a systematic review and meta-analysis. Bull World Health Organ. 2015. May 1;93(5):339–346C. 10.2471/BLT.14.146951 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 17.Glanz K, Bishop DB. The role of behavioral science theory in development and implementation of public health interventions. Annu Rev Public Health. 2010;31(1):399–418. 10.1146/annurev.publhealth.012809.103604 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 18.Burt RD, Peterson AV Jr. Smoking cessation among high school seniors. Prev Med. 1998. May-Jun;27(3):319–27. 10.1006/pmed.1998.0269 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 19.Kaplan CP, Nápoles-Springer A, Stewart SL, Pérez-Stable EJ. Smoking acquisition among adolescents and young Latinas: the role of socioenvironmental and personal factors. Addict Behav. 2001. Jul-Aug;26(4):531–50. 10.1016/S0306-4603(00)00143-X [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 20.Vogt S, Mohmmed Zaid NA, El Fadil Ahmed H, Fehr E, Efferson C. Changing cultural attitudes towards female genital cutting. Nature. 2016. October 27;538(7626):506–9. 10.1038/nature20100 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 21.Valente TW, Pumpuang P. Identifying opinion leaders to promote behavior change. Health Educ Behav. 2007. December;34(6):881–96. 10.1177/1090198106297855 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 22.UNFPA-UNICEF joint evaluation of the UNFPA-UNICEF joint programme on female genital mutilation/cutting (FGM/C): accelerating change. 2008–2013. Volume 1. New York: United Nations Population Fund & United Nations Children’s Fund: 2013. Available from: https://www.unfpa.org/admin-resource/unfpa-unicef-joint-evaluation-unfpa-unicef-joint-programme-female-genital [cited 2021 May 26].
  • 23.Schimmelpfennig R, Vogt S, Ehret S, Efferson C. Promotion of behavioural change for health in a heterogeneous population – Supplementary Information 1. London: figshare; 2021. 10.6084/m9.figshare.15035379 10.6084/m9.figshare.15035379 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
  • 24.Krumpal I. Determinants of social desirability bias in sensitive surveys: a literature review. Qual Quant. 2013;47(4):2025–47. 10.1007/s11135-011-9640-9 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 25.Hakim S, Chowdhury MAB, Uddin MJ. Correlates of attempting to quit smoking among adults in Bangladesh. Addict Behav Rep. 2018. April 26;8:1–7. 10.1016/j.abrep.2018.04.002 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 26.Powell LM, Tauras JA, Ross H. The importance of peer effects, cigarette prices and tobacco control policies for youth smoking behavior. J Health Econ. 2005. September;24(5):950–68. 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2005.02.002 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 27.Brunson EK. The impact of social networks on parents’ vaccination decisions. Pediatrics. 2013. May;131(5):e1397–404. 10.1542/peds.2012-2452 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 28.Bish A, Yardley L, Nicoll A, Michie S. Factors associated with uptake of vaccination against pandemic influenza: a systematic review. Vaccine. 2011. September 2;29(38):6472–84. 10.1016/j.vaccine.2011.06.107 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 29.Bauch CT. Imitation dynamics predict vaccinating behaviour. Proc Biol Sci. 2005. August 22;272(1573):1669–75. 10.1098/rspb.2005.3153 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 30.Oraby T, Thampi V, Bauch CT. The influence of social norms on the dynamics of vaccinating behaviour for paediatric infectious diseases. Proc Biol Sci. 2014. February 12;281(1780):20133172. 10.1098/rspb.2013.3172 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 31.Rimal RN, Storey JD. Construction of meaning during a pandemic: the forgotten role of social norms. Health Commun. 2020. December;35(14):1732–4. 10.1080/10410236.2020.1838091 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 32.Kim DA, Hwong AR, Stafford D, Hughes DA, O’Malley AJ, Fowler JH, et al. Social network targeting to maximise population behaviour change: a cluster randomised controlled trial. Lancet. 2015. July 11;386(9989):145–53. 10.1016/S0140-6736(15)60095-2 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 33.Schimmelpfennig R, Vogt S, Ehret S, Efferson C. Promotion of behavioural change for health in a heterogeneous population – Supplementary Information 2. London: figshare; 2021. 10.6084/m9.figshare.15035373 10.6084/m9.figshare.15035373 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
  • 34.Gangarosa EJ, Galazka AM, Wolfe CR, Phillips LM, Gangarosa RE, Miller E, et al. Impact of anti-vaccine movements on pertussis control: the untold story. Lancet. 1998. January 31;351(9099):356–61. 10.1016/S0140-6736(97)04334-1 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 35.Bauch CT, Bhattacharyya S. Evolutionary game theory and social learning can determine how vaccine scares unfold. PLOS Comput Biol. 2012;8(4):e1002452. 10.1371/journal.pcbi.1002452 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 36.Volpp KG, Cannuscio CC. Incentives for immunity – strategies for increasing Covid-19 vaccine uptake. N Engl J Med. 2021. July 1;385(1):e1. 10.1056/NEJMp2107719 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 37.Banerjee A, Chandrasekhar AG, Dalpath S, Duflo E, Floretta J, Jackson MO, et al. Selecting the most effective nudge: evidence from a large-scale experiment on immunization. Working paper 28726. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research; 2021. 10.3386/w28726 10.3386/w28726 [DOI]
  • 38.Walkey AJ, Law A, Bosch NA. Lottery-based incentive in Ohio and COVID-19 vaccination rates. JAMA. 2021. July 2;326(8):766–7. https://jamanetwork.com/journals/jama/article-abstract/2781792 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 39.Campos-Mercade P, Meier AN, Schneider FH, Meier S, Pope D, Wengstrom E. Monetary incentives increase COVID-19 vaccinations. Science. 2021; October 7: 10.1126/science.abm0475 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 40.Milkman KL, Patel MS, Gandhi L, Graci HN, Gromet DM, Ho H, et al. A megastudy of text-based nudges encouraging patients to get vaccinated at an upcoming doctor’s appointment. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA. 2021. May 18;118(20):e2101165118. 10.1073/pnas.2101165118 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 41.Schmelz K. Enforcement may crowd out voluntary support for COVID-19 policies, especially where trust in government is weak and in a liberal society. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA. 2021. January 5;118(1):e2016385118. 10.1073/pnas.2016385118 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 42.Loewenstein G, Cryder C. Why paying people to be vaccinated could backfire. The New York Times. 2020 Dec 14. Available from: https://www.nytimes.com/2020/12/14/upshot/covid-vaccine-payment.html. [cited 2021 Jul 2].
  • 43.Promberger M, Marteau TM. When do financial incentives reduce intrinsic motivation? Comparing behaviors studied in psychological and economic literatures. Health Psychol. 2013. September;32(9):950–7. 10.1037/a0032727 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 44.Esteves-Sorenson C, Broce R. Do monetary incentives undermine performance on intrinsically enjoyable tasks? A field test. Rev Econ Stat. 2020:1–46. 10.1162/rest_a_00947 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 45.Efferson C, Lalive R, Richerson PJ, Mcelreath R, Lubell M. Conformists and mavericks: the empirics of frequency-dependent cultural transmission. Evol Hum Behav. 2008;29(1):56–64. 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2007.08.003 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 46.Muthukrishna M, Morgan TJH, Henrich J. The when and who of social learning and conformist transmission. Evol Hum Behav. 2016;37(1):10–20. 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2015.05.004 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 47.Murphy J, Vallières F, Bentall RP, Shevlin M, McBride O, Hartman TK, et al. Psychological characteristics associated with COVID-19 vaccine hesitancy and resistance in Ireland and the United Kingdom. Nat Commun. 2021. January 4;12(1):29. 10.1038/s41467-020-20226-9 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]

Articles from Bulletin of the World Health Organization are provided here courtesy of World Health Organization

RESOURCES