Abstract
Technological innovations drive the evolution of human societies. The success of innovations depends not only on their actual benefits but also on how potential adopters perceive them and how their beliefs are affected by their social and cultural environment. To deepen our understanding of socio-psychological processes affecting the new technology spread, we model the joint dynamics of three interlinked processes: individual learning and mastering the new technology, changes in individual attitudes towards it, and changes in individual adoption decisions. We assume that the new technology can potentially lead to a higher benefit but achieving it requires learning. We posit that individual decision-making process as well as their attitudes are affected by cognitive dissonance and conformity with peers and an external authority. Individuals vary in different psychological characteristics and in their attitudes. We investigate both transient dynamics and long-term equilibria observed in our model. We show that early adopters are usually individuals who are characterized by low cognitive dissonance and low conformity with peers but are sensitive to the effort of an external authority promoting the innovation. We examine the effectiveness of five different intervention strategies aiming to promote the diffusion of a new technology: training individuals, providing subsidies for early adopters, increasing the visibility of peer actions, simplifying the exchange of opinions between people, and increasing the effort of an external authority. We also discuss the effects of culture on the spread of innovations. Finally, we demonstrate that neglecting the cognitive forces and the dynamic nature of individual attitudes can lead to wrong conclusions about adoption of innovations. Our results can be useful in developing more efficient policies aiming to promote the spread of new technologies in different societies, cultures and countries.
Keywords: diffusion of technological innovations, conformity, social norms, cognitive dissonance, dynamics of attitudes and beliefs
1. Introduction
Diffusion of technological innovations has been a major force of productivity growth throughout human prehistory and history [1,2]. For example, the spread of agriculture and innovative warfare technologies has promoted the emergence of complex societies [3,4]. It has been argued that technology diffusion has controlled the evolution of the world’s cross-country income distribution [5,6], that it can explain the structure of the world after World War II [7], and that it is a primary contributor to trade cycles [8,9]. The spread of technological innovations such as cell phones, digital television, personal computers, online banking and the Internet is changing our daily lives [10,11].
History shows though that even highly beneficial innovations can fail to spread [12,13]. Therefore, understanding how innovations spread is of great importance for businesses, governments and policy makers. Consequently, the process of the diffusion of technological innovations has been studied intensively in different fields including economics [14], marketing [15], political science [16–18], sociology [19] and anthropology [20].
Mathematical modelling has been widely used to explain and predict the diffusion of innovations starting with the seminal work of Bass [21]. Different approaches are used. Aggregate models typically use differential equations to describe the dynamics of the overall number of adopters of a new technology [22–24]. Although this approach provides a simple and often analytically tractable way for studying aggregate dynamics, it does not capture the process of individual decision-making, differences between individuals related to it, the structure and the intensity of connections between individuals, and their personal attitudes and beliefs. These limitations can be overcome with agent-based modelling (ABM) which explicitly focuses on the decision-making process and on social influences experienced by individuals [10,22,25]. In this approach, the macro-level dynamics emerge from aggregated behaviours of individuals. The vast majority of the ABM-related literature on the innovation diffusion focuses on the influence of the topological structure of social networks [26–29] including the role of social hubs [30] or the degree of the network connectivity [31] on the spread of innovations. There is also plenty of work investigating the effects of opinion leaders, word-of-mouth peer influence and social contagions [32,33].
While the social network structure is important, there are many other crucial psychological, cultural and cognitive aspects of human decision-making affecting the spread of innovations. For example, incorrect beliefs about the health and environmental effects of traditional stoves, which use wood, agricultural waste, coal and dried cattle manure, relative to those of improved cooking stoves have greatly reduced the spread of the latter in rural India [34]. Initial attempts to introduce piped drinking water made in 1950s in Uttar Pradesh, India, failed because potential adopters had negative attitudes towards the new technology due to perceived harmful effects of drinking electrically pumped water, tastelessness of this water and fears that the water was medicated to reduce fertility [35,36]. In the US home VCR market during the 1980s, the VHS format won competition over Betamax because consumers developed beliefs about its growth advantage [37], which became a ‘self-fulfilling prophecy’ [38]. It is also well recognized that social influences and social norms can play a crucial role in the innovation diffusion processes [39–43]. There are two general types of social norms [44–47]. Descriptive norms describe the perceptions of how others are behaving, such as whether one perceives their neighbours to be adopting the innovative technology [45], while injunctive norms consider the perceived expectations from others regarding a behaviour, such as feedback giving social approval for using the new technology [45]. Injunctive norms are sustained by the threat of social disapproval/punishment for norm violations and/or by norm internalization [44,48]. The literature on the innovation diffusion typically focuses on the effect of conformity and descriptive norms [49,50] while largely ignoring the effect of injunctive norms (see [51] for a rare exception).
Social norms imply conformity with behaviour and attitudes of others. Injunctive norms also include the second-order beliefs about others. Attitudes and beliefs of individuals can change in time as they interact and accumulate information about the product and the behaviour and attitudes of others as in the case of the three-stone stove in some African communities [35]. Therefore, accounting for the dynamics of beliefs can lead to a better understanding of the innovation diffusion. Modelling the dynamics of beliefs necessitates the consideration of cognitive dissonance induced by a mismatch between actions and beliefs which promotes negative emotions and discomfort [52]. To reduce the dissonance between attitudes and actions, individuals can change their attitudes via a post-factum justification of a product purchase or a technology use, or alternatively they can change their behaviour via withdrawal of the action causing the dissonance [52,53]. While some experiments studied the adoption of a new technology in situations with a mismatch between its actual performance and attitudes towards it [54–56], this phenomenon apparently has not been included yet in the innovation diffusion models.
The cultural and psychological factors just discussed have been repeatedly demonstrated to be important in decision-making [57–63]. There is a suite of corresponding mathematical models developed in economics and cultural evolution. For example, the effects of personal attitudes have been included in models of utility functions [64–68] some of which allowed for personal attitudes to change as a result of cognitive dissonance [64,65,69]. Such changes are often described by linear equations similar to those used in models of the spread of opinions [70–73]. The effects of injunctive norms and expected disapproval (or punishment) by peers and/or external authorities have been modelled by introducing additional components to the utility function [48,74–77].
However, these theoretical advances have been largely neglected in mathematical models of innovation diffusion. Here we seek to remove these limitations. Our goal will be to explore the effects of individual variation, culture, psychology and interventions on the success or failure of innovations. We will use recent advances in modelling the dynamics of actions, attitudes and beliefs of heterogeneous individuals in social dilemmas [48,76–78]. Specifically, we will build and study a model describing the joint dynamics of three important processes: individual learning and mastering a new technology, the evolution of individual attitudes towards the new technology and the evolution of individual adoption decisions. By an individual attitude, we will mean the individual perception of the desirability of its use. In our model, decisions and attitudes of individuals will affect each other through cognitive dissonance and conformity, will coevolve with existing social norms and will be subject to external influence (e.g. via advertising and mass media). Moreover, we will explore the effects of heterogeneity between individuals in different psychological and normative characteristics. Including social and psychological factors will allow us to capture the role of interpersonal and inter-group differences in various cultural characteristics (such as the degrees of individualism-collectivism, future orientation and rationality) in shaping innovation diffusion patterns. We will also consider and contrast the efficiency of several intervention strategies aiming to promote the diffusion of new technologies.
Below, after introducing our model in §2, we provide the results of its analysis in §3. We will first discuss analytical results on equilibria in some simple cases and then follow with a description of agent-based simulations of the general model. We will focus on the effects of various parameters on the frequency of adopters and individual attitudes. At the end, we will examine the effectiveness of different intervention strategies.
2. The model
We consider a society with N members manufacturing individually some product. We treat time as discrete. Each individual can use one of two technologies which we will call ‘old’ and ‘new’. The type of technology used is specified by variable x taking values 0 or 1 (0 means ‘old’ and 1 means ‘new’). The frequency of adopters of the new technology is specified by variable p. Individuals also differ in their attitude y towards the new technology (0 ≤ y ≤ 1) which affects the likelihood of its adoption and which is influenced by perceived long-term material and normative benefits, social influences (by peers and external authorities) and cognitive processes. For example, for somebody who cares mostly about material rewards or about the employment of local people, attitude y towards open-pit mining can be very high, whereas for people who care mostly about protecting environment it can be quite low. Similarly, even if fracking is currently not too profitable, somebody who believes it has a bright future will have high attitude y towards it. We assume that using the old technology results in a certain benefit. (Throughout the paper, by ‘benefit’ we understand the benefit per unit of time which can be measured in some currency.) The new technology can potentially lead to a higher benefit but achieving it requires learning. The benefit b of new technology depends on how long the individual has used it and on some individual characteristics. Summarizing, each individual is characterized by three dynamically changing variables: x, y and b. We postulate that the individual adoption process is influenced by expected material benefits, by the behaviour of peers, by the messaging of an authority promoting the new technology and by personal attitude towards it. The latter can change dynamically as a result of psychological processes and different social influences. To add further realism, we allow for variation between individuals (due to cultural and psychological differences) in certain parameters specifying how these variables change. Figure 1 illustrates the structure of our model.
Figure 1.
Model structure. The model integrates three interlinked processes: individual decision-making process regarding technology use, the dynamics of individual attitudes towards a new technology, and individual learning process in mastering the new technology. An individual chooses a technology by maximizing their utility function that integrates an expected material pay-off and a normative value. The expected material pay-off depends on the benefit of using a new technology, which is formed as a result of a learning process. The learning process encompasses two effects: (i) individuals can get higher benefits through repetition of an activity (i.e. learning by doing) and (ii) individuals can learn from others who use the same technology. The normative component of the utility function depends on individual attitudes (through cognitive dissonance), on the actions and attitudes of others (as a result of conformity with peers), and on the message of an external authority (as a result of conformity with the authority). The attitude of an individual, in turn, changes as a result of cognitive dissonance, conformity with peers’ actions and attitudes, and conformity with the authority.
2.1. Benefit of new technology
We assume that the benefit of using the old technology is specified by a constant b0 which is the same for all people. An individual who is just starting to use the new technology gets benefit bmin while a complete mastery of the new technology brings benefit bmax. It is natural to assume that bmin ≤ b0 ≤ bmax. The individual benefit of the new technology b can also be viewed as a measure of the skills of using it.
We postulate that two processes influence the dynamics of benefit b. The first process is learning by doing which leads to higher benefits through repetition of an activity [79–81]. To capture this effect we assume each use of the new technology increases benefit b towards bmax at a rate 0 ≤ a ≤ 1 specific to this individual [82,83]. Note that rate a can be viewed as an ‘absorptive capacity’ in terms of [84].
The second process is associated with knowledge depreciation and production breakdown [85–91]. We assume that each time step when the individual does not use the new technology, their skills decline towards bmin at rate 0 ≤ c ≤ 1. We describe the effects of these two processes on the benefit b of the new technology for a focal individual using a recurrence equation
2.1 |
where the prime means the next time moment.
Below, we will consider the knowledge depreciation rate c, which can also be treated as the rate of loss of practical skills of using the new technology due to the lack of practice, as a constant. Although, in general, c can be individual-specific, for the sake of simplicity, we will assume it is the same for all individuals. In contrast, we will assume that the learning rate a depends on the frequency of adopters p
where a0 and a1 are constant individual-specific positive parameters. For example, the amount of information about the new technology available through specialized guides, forums and courses [84] can increase with p, which would help new users become more comfortable with the new technology increasing their rate of learning a. To guarantee that the learning rate a is between 0 and 1, we assume that a0 + a1 ≤ 1.
For an individual continuously using the new technology, equation (2.1) would generate a learning curve [85,92–96] approaching bmax asymptotically.
2.2. Decision-making process
We assume that individuals update their choice of technology randomly and independently with probability ν per time step. When this happens, they choose x in an attempt to maximize a utility function which combines an expected material benefit, , and a psychological value V(x, y):
2.2 |
where ε is a parameter scaling the relative importance of normative and psychological factors in the utility function. Specifically,
where the expected difference in utilities ΔU(y, b) = U(1, y, b) − U(0, y, b). The latter can be written as , where the difference in pay-off between the two actions and the corresponding difference in values ΔV(y) = V(1, y) − V(0, y).
When using agent-based simulations, we will assume that individuals use myopic best response with errors with precision parameter λ [97]. (If λ = 0, individuals make decisions completely randomly; if precision is infinity, i.e. λ = ∞, individuals always make the decisions maximizing their utility.)
We note that accounting for normative factors is becoming more common in modelling human decision-making [48,74,77,98–102].
2.2.1. Expected material benefit
We describe the individual perception of an expected material benefit of using technology x given their current benefit b as
2.3 |
The equation corresponding to choosing x = 1 implies that when considering the material benefits of the new technology, individuals take into account not only their current benefit b, but also the maximum possible future benefit bmax, with a foresight parameter 0 ≤ ω ≤ 1 being the weight of the future benefit. Our approach can be interpreted within a framework of foresight [103–105]. More generally, foresight is related to the notions of prospection [106] and inter-temporal choices when people have to trade off costs and benefits at different points in time [107,108].
2.2.2. Psychological effects
We postulate that besides material benefits, individuals can also pay certain psychological costs or get certain psychological benefits as a result of their actions. First, there is a psychic cost if there is a mismatch between their action x and attitude y due to cognitive dissonance [109]. We also postulate that individuals expect disapproval from those who use a different technology and approval from those who use the same technology [110]. We assume that individuals know the average attitude of their peers (e.g. through direct or on-line discussions) and experience additional psychological pay-off depending on whether their action aligns or not with [76]. Finally, we postulate the existence of an external authority (e.g. government policies, advertising campaign or mass media) promoting the new technology so that individuals get additional psychic benefit or pay psychic cost if they follow or not the recommendation of the external authority [111].
Electronic supplementary material, equation (S1) combines all these effects into a normative value V(x, y). Then the difference ΔV(y) = V(1, y) − V(0, y) in psychological pay-offs between choosing x = 1 and x = 0 for an individual with attitude y is
2.4 |
where parameters v, k1, k2 and k3 measure the effect of cognitive dissonance, of injunctive social norms, of conformity with peers and of conformity with (or trust to) the authority, respectively. All these parameters are individual-specific. Note that ΔV(y) depends of both the average behaviour (p) and the average attitude () in the population.
2.3. The dynamics of attitudes
We postulate that after taking an action (i.e. choosing the technology to use) individuals observe the actions of their peers, get ideas about their average attitude through some interactions and are subject to influence by the external authority. As a result of these forces they then go through a psychological process of revising their attitude y. Specifically, we account for the effects of cognitive dissonance as well as for conformity with peers’ actions and attitudes towards the new technology, and with an external authority promoting its usage. Adapting the approach of Gavrilets [76], we describe these processes using a recurrence equation
2.5 |
The four terms in the brackets act to align the individual’s attitude y with their action x, with the average action p of their peers, with the average attitude of peers and with the action x = 1 promoted by the authority, respectively. Parameter s measures the speed of change in attitude while parameters α, β1, β2 and β3 are the relative strengths of cognitive dissonance and the three conformity forces (α + β1 + β2 + β3 = 1). Parameter β3 also reflects the trust to the message of the authority. All these parameters are individual-specific. Parameters of the model are summarized in table 1.
Table 1.
Most important variables, functions and parameters (also see electronic supplementary material, table S1).
symbols | their meaning | |
---|---|---|
variables | x | individual choice: old (x = 0) or new (x = 1) technology |
y | individual attitude towards the new technology (0 ≤ y ≤ 1) | |
b | individual benefit/skill of using the new technology | |
functions | p | frequency of adopters, |
a(p) | individual learning rate, a(p) = a0 + a1 p | |
perceived material benefit, equation (2.3) | ||
V(x, y) | normative component in the utility function, electronic supplementary material, equation (S1) | |
U(x, y, b) | utility function, equation (2.2) | |
parameters | b0 | individual benefit of using old technology |
bmin, bmax | minimum and maximum benefits of using new technology | |
c | knowledge depreciation rate | |
a0, a1 | learning parameters | |
ω | foresight parameter | |
v, α, D | cognitive dissonance parameters (D = (v + α)/2) | |
k1, β1, K1 | conformity with peers’ actions parameters (K1 = (k1 + β1)/2) | |
k2, β2, K2 | conformity with peers’ attitudes parameters (K2 = (k2 + β2)/2) | |
k3, β3, K3 | conformity with authority parameters (K3 = (k3 + β3)/2) | |
ɛ | strength of normative factors in the utility function | |
λ | precision parameter | |
control variables | p0, bs | proportion of trained individuals and the subsidy to first adopters |
f0, f1, f3, f4 | parameters scaling the effects of cognitive dissonance, visibility of peers’ actions, visibility of peers’ attitudes, and authority’s effort |
Before proceeding with analysis, we want to stress two things. First, all socio-psychological factors included in our model have been repeatedly shown to be important in decision-making (see the references above). Second, the linear functions we used to capture these effects (see equations (2.4) and (2.5)) are both the simplest possible mathematically and also standard in models of social behaviour. For example, the terms analogous to components v(2y − 1), k1(2p − 1), and k3 of the utility function present in equation (2.4) are present in various game-theoretic models (e.g. [51,76,112–115]). Moreover, the linear relationships can be very easily tested statistically on real data. Similarly, our equation (2.5) is an adaptation of the standard approach in social influence models [70–73,116–118] which use linear equations for describing the dynamics of personal attitudes and opinions as a result of the exchange of opinions between group members.
3. Results
We have analysed this model using numerical simulations and analytical approximations. We will start by discussing analytical results on equilibria when there is no variation in individual parameters and then follow with numerical studies of the general model. We will focus on the effects of various parameters on the frequency of adopters p and individual attitudes y. At the end, we will examine the effectiveness of different intervention strategies aiming to promote the diffusion of the new technology and how their effectiveness depends on cultural characteristics of the society.
3.1. Equilibria in the symmetric case
Assume that variation in individual parameters is absent and there are no errors in the decision-making process (λ = ∞). In this case, the system converges to an equilibrium where each adopter attains the maximum benefit of using the new technology bmax and each non-adopter has the minimum benefit of the new technology bmin.
There are three possible types of equilibria: a complete failure of the new technology (so that p* = 0), a complete replacement of the old technology by the new one (so that p* = 1) and the coexistence of two technologies (so that 0 < p* < 1), respectively. The equilibria of the first two types will be called homogeneous, and the equilibria of the last type will be called heterogeneous. Figure 2 illustrates convergence to different equilibria.
Figure 2.
Convergence to equilibria in four independent runs with no between-individual variation and no errors in decision-making. Shown are: the frequency of adopters p (top row) individual attitudes y (middle row), and individual benefits b (bottom row). Different individuals are shown by different colours. The values of parameter ω are shown below the graphs. Other parameters: bmin = 0.5, b0 = 1, bmax = 2.4, a0 = a1 = 0.05, c = 0.1, v = k1 = k2 = k2 = α = β1 = β2 = β3 = 0.25, ɛ =0.5, s = 0.1, N = 1000, ν = 0.1, λ = ∞. Initial values of y are drawn randomly and independently from a beta distribution with mean 0.5 and standard deviation 0.2.
At the equilibrium with p* = 0 (see figure 2a), where nobody uses the new technology, individuals still have some positive attitude towards it
due to the influence of the external authority. This attitude increases with β3 and the strength of conformity with peers’ attitude β2. The conditions for local stability of this equilibrium are given in the electronic supplementary material, SM. A sufficient condition for its instability and, thus, for some use of the new technology (i.e. for p* > 0) is
that is, the perceived material gain from using new technology for the first time () plus the effect of the external authority (εk3) is larger than the joint effect of cognitive dissonance (εv) and conformity with peers (εk1, εk2).
At equilibrium with p* = 1 (figure 2c,d), all individuals have the maximum attitude towards the new technology, i.e. y* = 1; this equilibrium is always locally stable under our assumptions about parameters.
The heterogeneous equilibria (figure 2b) form a ‘line’ of equilibria with plow < p* < phigh, where the boundaries plow, phigh are defined in the electronic supplementary material. At the heterogeneous equilibria, the attitudes of adopters and non-adopters differ by the value equal to the strength of cognitive dissonance: . If β2 = 0 (so that, there are no direct discussions between individuals), the expressions for and take a particularly simple form:
3.1 |
As expected, both attitudes increase with the frequency of adopters (p*). The corresponding equations for the case of β2 > 0 are considered in the electronic supplementary material.
Interestingly, different heterogeneous equilibria can be simultaneously stable with other heterogeneous equilibria as well as with the homogeneous equilibria with p* = 0 and p* = 1, so that the eventual outcome can depend on initial conditions and chance. For example, figure 2b,c illustrates the coexistence of two types of equilibria: depending on the initial values of attitudes y, the system either converges to a heterogeneous equilibrium (shown in figure 2b), or to a homogeneous equilibrium with all individuals using the new technology (shown in figure 2c).
3.2. Agent-based simulations
To study more complex cases of our model where analytical progress is impossible we use agent-based simulations. In our simulations, individual parameters v, k1, k2 and k3 are chosen from a broken stick distribution on [0, 1]. Similarly, parameters α, β1, β2 and β3 are chosen from a broken stick distribution on [0, 1] as well. (The advantage of the broken-stick distribution [119,120] is that it has no parameters.) We also assume that individual values of parameters a1, ω and ε are drawn randomly and independently from truncated normal distributions with means and standard deviations σa1, σω and σε, respectively. Parameters c = 0.1, b0 = 1, ν = 0.1, s = 0.1, N = 1000, λ = 15 are constant. Unless otherwise stated, . Initial attitudes towards new technology are drawn randomly and independently from a beta distribution with a small mean value (unless otherwise stated, ) and standard deviation 0.2. We assume that initially the number of new technology adopters is zero (i.e. x = 0 for each individual). Initially, the benefit of new technology is minimal (i.e. b = bmin).
With finite precision, the system converges asymptotically either to the equilibrium with p* = 0 or p* = 1. In general, the time to convergence can be large so that transient dynamics are of more relevance and interest. Therefore, we focus on the behaviour of the system at some time step T. In simulations, we consider three different time steps T = 50, 100 and 200. The choice of other parameters is discussed below. Unless otherwise stated, the results shown are based on 100 runs for each parameter combination.
3.2.1. Effects of perceived material pay-offs
Intuitively, increasing the maximum bmax and minimum bmin benefit of new technology as well as increasing the weight ω individuals put on future material benefits should simplify the spread of new technology. Results of numerical simulations support these intuitions. Figure 3 shows that the frequency of adopters as well as the attitudes of individuals increase with bmax, bmin and . The difference between attitudes of adopters and non-adopters is approximately equal to the average of the cognitive dissonance parameter which is in line with our analytical results above. Note that the effects of parameters on frequency p are large relative to their effects on attitudes y. This happens because they have direct effects on individuals’ actions, while their effects on individual attitudes are indirect.
Figure 3.
The dependence of the frequency of adopters p and attitudes y on: (a) the maximum benefit parameter bmax, (b) the minimum benefit parameter bmin, (c) the foresight parameter . Each point corresponds to an outcome of a particular run. Characteristics were calculated at T = 100. (The graphs corresponding to T = 50 and 200 are very similar to the ones shown.) Attitudes of adopters and non-adopters are marked in red and blue colours, respectively. Curves show the average values of corresponding characteristics among all runs. Baseline parameters: .
Figure 3 also shows some decline in the attitude of non-adopters for large values of bmax, bmin and when p becomes close to one. What happens is that a small number of remaining non-adopters represent a very biased sample of individuals characterized by very strong cognitive dissonance (i.e. large values of v0 and α) in comparison with adopters. Typically, non-adopters also have low sensitivity to the influence of the external authority (i.e. small k3 and β3) compared with those who adopt the new technology. All these differences are significant at the 10% level. For more details, see electronic supplementary material, figure S2. Also, there is a large variation in average attitudes of non-adopters between different runs if p is close to 1, that is, when there are few non-adopters. Their average attitude is then highly dependent on attitudes of each of these few individuals, so that it is highly dependent on initial attitudes and other model parameters (such as a1, ω, ɛ) which are randomly drawn from fixed distributions.
3.2.2. Effects of policy interventions
Here we examine the effectiveness of five different intervention strategies aiming to promote the diffusion of a new technology in the society: training individuals, providing subsidies for early adopters, increasing the visibility of peer actions, simplifying the exchange of opinions between people and increasing the effort of the external authority to promote the innovation.
3.2.2.1. Training individuals
Assume that initially a small random fraction p0 of individuals are trained to use the new technology. In our model, the effect of training can be captured by assuming these individuals initially have maximum skills (b = bmax), choose the new technology (i.e. their x is set to 1), and have the maximum attitude y = 1 towards it. Initial conditions for all other individuals are generated as specified above. As expected, increasing the frequency of trained individuals p0 simplifies the spread of new technology (figure 4a). As we show in the electronic supplementary material, figure S3, this effect intensifies with an increase in the strength of normative factors . The reason is p0 affects individual actions and attitudes through cognitive dissonance and conformity with peers, which are stronger with larger ɛ.
Figure 4.
The dependence of the frequency of adopters p and attitudes y on: (a) the fraction of trained individuals p0, (b) the subsidy to early adopters bs, (c) increasing the visibility of peer actions f1, (d) simplifying the exchange of opinions between people f2, (e) increasing the effort of the external authority f3. Each point corresponds to an outcome of a particular run. Characteristics were calculated at T = 100. Attitudes of adopters and non-adopters are shown in red and blue colours, respectively. Curves show the average values of corresponding characteristics across all runs. Baseline parameters: .
3.2.2.2. Material support for early adopters
One of the widely used strategies to influence the diffusion process is to support early adopters through subsidies or tax benefits for new technology users [121]. This can be captured in our model by assuming that each person who starts using the new technology in the first few time steps, receives an additional one-time subsidy in the amount of bs. Typically, introducing a subsidy bs leads to an increase in p and y (figure 4b). We show in the electronic supplementary material, figure S4 that this strategy can be very efficient if the average foresight parameter is relatively large, and the average effect of normative factors is not large. The outcome is intuitive: increasing bs increases the perceived material pay-off associated with the new technology. Therefore, increasing bs leads to a substantial increase in p if the perceived material pay-off associated with the new technology is relatively large and important in comparison with normative factors.
Next we investigate the efficiency of three additional strategies of promoting the spread of innovation: (i) increasing the visibility of peer actions, (ii) simplifying the exchange of opinions between people, and (iii) increasing the effort of the external authority. In the model, we introduce these strategies via additional factors fi placed in front of the corresponding terms ki and βi of equations (2.4) and (2.5). For example, to study the effects of changing the effort of the external authority we would replace the terms k3 and β3(1 − y) in equations (2.4) and (2.5) with terms f3k3 and f3β3(1 − y). The changes in the effort of the external authority will then be modelled by changing the value of f3. While parameters k1, k2, k3 and β1, β2, β3 will vary between individuals, parameters f1, f2 and f3 will be the same for all individuals.
3.2.2.3. Increasing the visibility of peer actions
A change of the visibility of peer actions can be modelled by changing the value of f1. Typically, increasing f1 decreases the frequency of adopters p and the attitudes y (figure 4c). The reason is that strong conformity with peers’ decisions makes it difficult to start using the new technology initially when no one uses it. However, as shown in electronic supplementary material, figure S5, increasing f1 can lead to a slight increase in p in some special cases of the model that are discussed in the electronic supplementary material (for more details see electronic supplementary material, §S3.4).
3.2.2.4. Simplifying the exchange of opinions between people
This strategy involves creating a special environment in which individuals can discuss what they think about the new technology. Examples include creating special Internet forums or social events related to the new technology, where participants can meet each other and share their attitudes towards the new technology. In our model, this can be captured by increasing the factor f2. Typically, increasing f2 decreases the frequency of adopters p (figure 4d). The result is intuitive: initially all individuals have low attitudes towards the new technology. Therefore, increasing the strength of conformity with peers’ attitudes prevents the adoption in the early stages of the process. Increasing f2 coupled with a decay in p leads to a decrease in attitudes of adopters (through conformity with peers’ attitudes and actions, respectively). However, as shown in electronic supplementary material, figure S6, increasing f2 can lead to a slight increase in p in some special cases of the model that are discussed in the electronic supplementary material (for more details see electronic supplementary material, §S3.5).
3.2.2.5. Increasing the effort of the external authority
Increasing the effort of the external authority to promote the new technology (e.g. through an advertising campaign or propaganda) is captured by increasing parameter f3. Figure 4e shows that increasing f3 leads to an increase in attitudes of all individuals (as long as p < 1). In general, the frequency of adopters p shows an S-shaped dependence on f3. This implies that relatively small increases in f3 can in some cases lead to a substantial increase in p. The effectiveness of this intervention strategy is higher for larger values of and larger (see electronic supplementary material, figure S7). Figure 4e also shows some decline in the attitude of non-adopters for large values of f3. This is a general pattern observed if p is close to one. What happens is that a small number of remaining non-adopters represent a very biased sample of individuals characterized by very strong cognitive dissonance compared with adopters. Typically, non-adopters also have low sensitivity to the influence of their peers’ attitudes, and to the external authority compared with those who adopt the new technology. All these differences are significant at the 10% level. For more details, see electronic supplementary material, figure S8. We comment on the effects of the external authority further in the Discussion section.
3.2.3. Effects of cognitive and psychological factors
As expected, increasing the minimum learning rate a0 can lead to a substantial increase in the frequency of adopters p. By contrast, the effect of parameter a1 characterizing the sensitivity of the learning rate a to the frequency of adopters is mostly insignificant. This is so because a1 has almost no effect on the learning rate in early stages when p ≈ 0, while the effect of a0 does not depend on p directly. Electronic supplementary material, figures S9 and S10 illustrate these conclusions.
Next we consider the effects of two additional parameters. One is the relative strength of normative factors ε in the utility function (2.2). (Recall that if ɛ = 0, individuals care only about perceived material pay-offs. On the other hand, if ɛ = 1, the weights of perceived material pay-offs and psychological factors in the utility function are the same.) The other factor is the relative strength of cognitive dissonance. To investigate it, we will introduce an additional parameter f0 placed in front of the terms v(2y − 1) and α(x − y) in equations (2.4) and (2.5), respectively, and varying its value. If f0 = 0, cognitive dissonance is absent. On the other hand if f0 = 1, its effects are comparable to those of conformity. Parameter f0 will be the same for all individuals in the population. It has been argued that some human cultures are more collectivist than others and the effects of cognitive dissonance in such cultures can be significantly weaker than those of conformity [122]. Similarly the effects of material pay-offs versus immaterial influences can also vary between cultures. Therefore, parameters and f0 can also be viewed as reflecting certain cultural aspects.
3.2.3.1. Strength of normative factors ɛ
Effects of the relative strength of normative factors depend on the strength of conformity with the authority controlled by parameter f3. For relatively small f3, increasing leads to a decrease in the frequency of adopters p coupled with a decrease in attitudes of all individuals (figure 5a). What happens is that with small f3, conformity with peers, who initially do not use the new technology, dominates so that the overall effect of normative factors is negative for almost all individuals. Consequently, increasing basically amplifies this negative effect, preventing the spread of the new technology.
Figure 5.
The dependence of the frequency of adopters p and attitudes y on: (a,b) the strength of normative factors ɛ, (c,d) the strength of cognitive dissonance f0. Each point corresponds to an outcome of a particular run. Characteristics were calculated at T = 100. Attitudes of adopters and non-adopters are shown in red and blue colours, respectively. Curves show the average values of corresponding characteristics across all runs. Baseline parameters: , (a,b) and (c,d) .
Conversely, for relatively large f3, increasing the strength of normative factors increases the frequency of adopters p and attitudes y (figure 5b). What happens is that with large f3, conformity with the authority is strong so that the overall effect of normative factors is positive for a relatively large fraction of individuals. Increasing ɛ amplifies this positive effect. Electronic supplementary material, figure S11 provides further details on the interactions of different factors.
3.2.3.2. Cognitive dissonance
Increasing the strength of cognitive dissonance, which is controlled by parameter f0 decreases the frequency of adopters p (figure 5c,d). The reason is that strong cognitive dissonance makes it difficult to start using a new technology initially when the attitude towards it is low. This effect is quite more marked if is large. Increasing f0 has two main effects on y: (i) it forces individuals to align their attitudes with actions and (ii) it affects individual actions, which, in turn, have an impact on y through the conformity term. The former effect is positive for adopters, and negative for non-adopters. Since increasing f0 decreases p, the latter effect is negative. As a result, increasing f0 decreases attitudes of non-adopters (figures 5c,d). Attitudes of adopters can either increase (figure 5c) or decrease (figure 5d) with an increase in f0, depending on the size of the above opposing effects. The difference between attitudes of adopters and non-adopters is amplified by increasing f0. For more details, see electronic supplementary material, figure S12.
3.2.4. Dynamics of adoption
Here we consider who become early adopters of the new technology in our model. To simplify notation, we introduce the overall strength of cognitive dissonance D = (v + α)/2, of conformity with peers’ action K1 = (k1 + β1)/2, with peers’ attitudes, K2 = (k2 + β2)/2, and with external authority K3 = (k3 + β3)/2. Figure 6a shows that early adopters are characterized by lower degrees of cognitive dissonance D and conformity with peers K1, K2 and significantly higher sensitivity K3 to the external influence. There is no difference between adopters and non-adopters in the foresight parameter ω and the overall strength of normative factor ɛ. All the above conclusions are drawn at the 5% significance level. Strong sensitivity to the message of the external authority is necessary to overcome the expected drop in material pay-offs as well as the effects of cognitive dissonance and conformity with peers. After early adopters start using the new technology, other individuals one-by-one switch to using it (figure 6b). These observations are in line with our discussion above.
Figure 6.
Dynamics of adoption. (a) Average characteristics of adopters and non-adopters at T = 10. The averages and the 95% confidence intervals are calculated among 1000 independent runs. (b) An example of a single run: the frequency of adopters p, individuals attitudes y and individuals benefits b. Different individuals are shown by different colours related to their value of parameter K3. Individuals with the highest values of parameter K3 measuring conformity with the authority are shown in red, while those with smallest K3 are shown in blue. Other parameters: .
4. Discussion
Social influences have been a crucial factor in human evolution and behaviour since the origin of our species [123,124]. Social influences are also very important in the success or failure of many technological innovations, which is a well-known fact also reflected in many mathematical models starting with [21]. Understanding and predicting group behaviours, including those related to the adoption of innovations, is impossible without accounting for the differences between individuals in how they react to social influences. Starting with the pioneer work of [125–129] there are now many theoretical studies explicitly dealing with such differences, including those describing innovation diffusion [22,83]. One important aspect of between-individual variation is the difference in their psychology, attitudes and beliefs, which can change in time as individuals learn to take advantage of the new technology and as various social interactions they are engaged in unfold. Here we have aimed to understand better the effects of these processes on innovation diffusion.
Using recent advances in modelling the dynamics of actions, attitudes and beliefs in social dilemmas [48,76], we have built a novel model describing co-evolution of attitudes of individuals towards the new technology, their adoption decisions and their abilities to take advantage of it. In our model, individual decisions and changes in attitudes are controlled by cognitive dissonance, conformity with observed peers’ decisions, conformity with peers’ attitudes (revealed in direct discussions, online, etc.), and by an external influence (e.g. advertising or mass media). Our focus was on manufacturing a product using a new technology which requires certain time investment to achieve a desired efficiency. However, our model also applies to consumers trying to take advantage of a new product.
There are many, largely overlapping, theories of behaviour and behavioural change across the social and behavioural sciences [130]. Our approach can be viewed as an extension of earlier continuous opinions and discrete actions (CODA) models [28,131,132] in which actions of individuals depend on their attitudes (opinions) which in turn depend on observed behaviour of others. Our approach is also related to social psychology approaches [22,133,134], where adoption decisions are based on psychological rules rather than perfect rationality. Specifically, our model can be viewed as an extension of models in [135,136] based on the theory of planned behaviour [137] which accounts for individual attitudes towards a technology and individual subjective norms. Earlier mathematical models have usually neglected the dynamic nature of individual attitudes. This, however, can lead to overestimation or underestimation of the number of adopters, as well as incorrect adoption curves (figure 7a). Moreover, ignoring the dynamic nature of attitudes can lead to wrong predictions of long-term equilibria (figure 7b). As a result, the predictive power of models and the effectiveness of the different policies based on them can be reduced.
Figure 7.
Effect of attitudes on the adoption curves. Examples of a single run of the model with dynamically changing attitudes (the black curve), fixed attitudes (the blue line, s = 0) and the model that does not take into account attitudes (the cyan line, s = 0 and v = k2 = α = β2 = 0 for all individuals) are shown. Baseline parameters: , (a) and (b) .
While there is an extensive literature on contagion of products, services, ideas and technologies based on social influence [32,33], the main focus of this literature is on network aspects of the diffusion process. On the contrary, in our work we emphasize on the individual decision-making, the co-evolution of individual actions and attitudes, on psychological, social and cultural aspects of these processes. This allows us to look from a new angle at well-known intervention strategies frequently used by different policy-makers, as well as to make theoretically grounded predictions about the success or failure of a particular technology in different cultural, regional or religious contexts.
4.1. Intervention strategies
We have used our model to evaluate the effectiveness of five different intervention strategies aiming to promote the diffusion of a new technology: (i) training individuals, (ii) providing subsidies for early adopters, (iii) increasing the visibility of peer actions, (iv) simplifying the exchange of opinions between people, and (v) increasing the effort of an external authority (such as cultural, social or political leaders or commercial advertisements). Our results show that training and subsidies can help spreading the innovation. Although this conclusion is intuitive, our models allow one to evaluate the resulting effects quantitatively. Increasing the visibility of peer actions and simplifying the exchange of opinions between people can have negative effect. The underlying cause of this is conformity with peers which acts against trying something new when the great majority of peers still use the old technology. An important caveat of our conclusions is that we assumed that both training and between-peer interactions were completely random. Targeting individuals with particular attitudes or increasing visibility of early adopters are expected to increase the positive effects of these interventions.
4.2. Conformity with authority
Our results show that the effort of external influence (measured by parameter f3 in our model) is the most important factor in the initial spread of innovations. This is hardly surprising and is well supported by empirical studies. For example, government effort was found to be critical in encouraging the adoption of sustainable technology in the Malaysian SMEs sector [138]. Effects of an external influence (via advertising or mass media) have already been studied extensively [22,139–142]. It has been argued that advertising mostly contributes to the spread of initial awareness about the innovation, rather than to its adoption [22]. Goldenberg et al. [141] concluded that the effect of external influences is strong at early stages of the diffusion process and decreases in time. Here we assumed that all individuals were already aware of the new technology and the effort of the external authority was directed towards exploiting individual tendencies to comply with propaganda [143,144] by modifying both the behaviour and attitudes. By the authority we mean companies producing the innovation, governments, local or global authorities aiming to promote some strategic innovations, and/or opinion leaders or influential others agitating for a new product or technology. Our results show (figure 6) that it is the individuals who are most affected by the external influence who are the first to start using the new technology.
In our model, the effect of the external authority was limited to messaging about potential benefits of the new technology. However the authority can take a much more active and powerful role. For example, the adoption of the 3D printing (or additive manufacturing) technology was very slow during the 2000s, despite its demonstrated feasibility [145] due to engineering norms existing at that time [146]. (The terms ‘3D printing’ and ‘additive manufacturing’ refer to a technology that allows the engineer to realize a geometry conceived in a computer-aided design software to a product in one step by fusing various material feedstocks including powder, wire and tapes in a layer-by-layer fashion [147]. The foundational knowledge of this technology can be traced back to rapid prototyping, i.e. a process for rapidly creating the shape of a manufactured component for quick evaluation before releasing to mass production by traditional manufacturing processes that rely on pre-existing worldwide supply chain.) To accelerate the adoption of the 3D printing, leaders in the US government, academia and industry developed a focused effort to leverage emerging technologies in advanced manufacturing. As a part of this initiative, President Obama announced in June 2011 the launch of the public-private partnership dedicated to deployment of additive manufacturing [148] which was followed by additional initiatives in 2012 [149]. Figure 8 illustrates the dramatic effect of President Obama’s announcement on the adoption of additive manufacturing and the 3D printing as tracked by Google Trends and Web of Science data (see also [150]).
Figure 8.
Effects of the President Obama’s announcement promoting the deployment of additive manufacturing. (a) Comparison of the normalized interest measured by Google Trends with reference to the technologies referred to as ‘rapid prototyping,’ ‘additive manufacturing,’ and '3D printing'. The normalized interest is measured as a search interest relative to the highest point on the chart for the given region and time. A value of 100 is the peak popularity for the term. A value of 50 means that the term is half as popular. A score of 0 means there was not enough data for this term. The vertical line corresponds to the month and year when President Obama announced the launch of the manufacturing institute mainly focused on additive manufacturing. (b) Comparison of normalized publications per year with key words additive manufacturing, and 3D printing shows rapid expansion after the launch date of the institute on additive manufacturing and overtaking the slowly evolving rapid prototyping technology. This is attributed to the slow realization of the benefits of this new technology by the engineering communities. The Web of Science data: the normalized publications per year is measured as the percentage of papers published that year that mention the corresponding term (3D printing, additive manufacturing, or rapid prototyping, respectively).
4.3. Psychological factors
We have also examined the effect of different psychological factors on the model dynamics. Our results show that individuals subject to strong cognitive dissonance as well as those exhibiting most conformity with the behaviour and attitudes of peers are less likely to be among the first adopters. On the other hand, simplifying learning process of the new technology increases its speed of adoption, as expected.
4.4. Effects of culture
Research shows that different geographic groups, cultures and countries can show significant differences in the psychological and normative characteristics of their populations. First, psychological research shows that cognitive dissonance is more likely to be expressed in some groups of individuals, societies and cultures than in others [122,151–153]. Second, societies and cultures vary in their ‘perception, preference, and social norms regarding time’ [154, p. 1]. Specifically, societies and cultures vary in their perception of the importance of future benefits and pay-offs [155]. In economic literature such time preferences are captured by a discounting rate. Cross-cultural work highlights the importance of culture in time discounting. Examples include studies of Canadian undergraduates and foreign undergraduates of Chinese descents [156], American, Chinese and Japanese graduate students living in the USA. [157], Israeli Arabs and Israeli Jews [158], as well as a comparison of 53 countries [159]. In psychology and social sciences, time preferences are reflected in a well-established cultural dimension of ‘future orientation’ which refers to the valuation of long-term versus short-term benefits [160,161]. Third, societies can vary in the extent to which individuals are influenced by actions and attitudes of others. For example, in collectivist societies individuals tend to align their actions with actions of their peers, while people in individualist societies care more about their own benefits and values [31,48,162].
In our model, the extent of future orientation (or the discounting rate) of a cultural group is controlled by the average value of the foresight parameter , the overall strength of normative factors relative to material pay-offs by the average value , and the strength of cognitive dissonance by parameter f0. We initially introduced parameters f1, f2 and f3 as measures of the strength of three different policy interventions. However, they can also be interpreted as culture-related measures of different types of the conformity in the society. For example, societies with small f1 and f2 can be viewed as individualist, while those with large f1 and f2 as collectivist; and societies with large f3 can be interpreted as those with a strong norm of conformity with (and trust to) the authority.
Looking at our results from this angle allows us to conclude that cultures most prone to adapting innovations will be more future-oriented and more sensitive to the message of the authority promoting the new technology. Existing data show that indeed future-oriented cultures encourage individuals to adopt a new technology, which can increase long-term economic performance [163], while (as discussed above) societies with strong conformity with the authority can exhibit high rates of innovations, if, for example, the authority prioritizes innovative activities [164].
Our model also predicts that societies with stronger cognitive dissonance are more resistant to new technologies and exhibit a higher difference between attitudes of adopters and non-adopters. In real life, adopters (or non-adopters) can organize in a community through, for example, Internet forums, which will intensify communications between the members of the community and prevent communications with individuals outside the group (because they have significantly different attitudes). As a result, the society may contain a number of groups of individuals using different technologies.
Our model predicts that, typically, individualist societies are more successful in the diffusion of new technologies than collectivist societies, especially in early stages of adoption. This result is well in line with the recent conclusions of [165], which showed that individualism has a positive effect on the diffusion speed in the early stage of adoption. We have also found that collectivist culture can be more successful in later stages of adoption in societies with high future orientation and strong sensitivity and trust to the message of the authority. This arises because future orientation and conformity with the authority mitigate negative effects of conformity with peers in early stages of adoption.
Finally, our results imply that societies with strong normative factors can be very successful in adopting the new technology if they have a strong norm of conformity with the authority. Conversely, if conformity with peers and/or cognitive dissonance dominate in individual decision-making, societies with a larger strength of normative factors are less successful. We have to stress though that our model does not include many other important factors affecting the spread of innovations such as economic, political and social influences and circumstances.
4.5. Tight–loose cultures and innovations
Empirical studies show that different countries, cultures and groups can vary in tightness–looseness scale. Tight societies are characterized by strong norms (e.g. personal, social or norms supported by governments or other authorities), and low tolerance to deviant behaviours, while loose societies are the opposite [166–168]. In our model, the strength of norms can be captured by parameter ɛ so that loose societies have lower values of ɛ than tight ones. Moreover, as pointed out in [169], loose societies are more diverse in terms of opinions and attitudes, because their culture encourages deviations and tolerates mistakes. As a result, we assume that the levels of heterogeneity in our model parameters and in initial attitudes towards the new technology are higher in loose societies, which promotes the spread of the new technology.
However, as shown in empirical research, some tight societies can be very successful in terms of innovativeness. For example, Chinese provinces with tighter cultures have higher rates of incremental innovations than looser provinces [164]. This can also be explained by the fact that the Chinese government has prioritized innovations over the past decades, which, coupled with a strong norm of conformity with the authority, fosters innovation diffusion in tight provinces. This empirical observation is well in line with our theoretical results: increasing the strength of normative factors ɛ can promote the strength of a new technology if there is a strong norm of conformity with the authority supporting this technology.
4.6. Social norms
Our results are also relevant for research on social norms [44–47,74,100,102,170–172]. In particular, variable y can be viewed as a personal norm with individuals experiencing dis-utility if their action x deviates from y. Individuals also experience dis-utility if their action deviates from the average behaviour and the average attitude in the group which can be viewed as measures of the descriptive and injunctive norms in the population. The loss of utility due to the deviation from the behaviour promoted by an external authority can also be viewed as emerging due to the injunctive norm imposed on the group. A novel component of our model relative to earlier modelling work on social norms [48,74,98,99,102] is that we allow for the personal value/attitude y to change. We have also accounted for additional factors such as different types of conformity.
4.7. Limitations and possible generalizations
Several limitations of our study should be pointed out. First, our model does not take into account the structure of interactions within the population assuming that all individuals have exactly the same information about their peers. The model can be generalized by assuming that interactions between individuals happen on a network [26–29]. This would allow us to study the effect of interactions between different socio-psychological and topological factors on the diffusion process. This will also allow us to model explicitly the effects of opinion leaders [141,173–176] and to examine the effectiveness of different more comprehensive targeting intervention strategies, e.g. targeting opinion leaders, different small groups of individuals located in different places of a network, or a small number of large groups [177]. One can also elaborate the model by adding a hierarchical group structure. With this extension, one can recognize different social norms, e.g. conformity with group-mates or global conformity. This would allow one to study co-evolution of diffusion processes in different ethnic or religious sub-populations within a society [178]. We have assumed that individuals make their decisions maximizing the utility function (with random errors). However, other strategy revision protocols can be considered, like simple repetition [133], reinforcement learning [179] or selective imitation [103]. We leave these extensions and generalizations for future work.
In our model, we did not consider other potential factors promoting the initial spread of innovations like status seeking or novelty seeking [180,181]. Neither did we analyse an additional potentially efficient strategy which is manipulating people’s beliefs about the efficiency of the innovation and about the frequency of people who have already adapted it.
Acknowledgements
We thank reviewers for comments and suggestions.
Data accessibility
The simulations were performed in MATLAB (Version R2019b). Data and relevant code for this research work are stored in GitHub: https://github.com/dtverskoi/The-spread-of-technological-innovations-effects-of-psychology-culture-and-policy-interventions and have been archived within the Zenodo repository: https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.5715314 [182].
Electronic supplementary material is available online [183].
Authors' contributions
D.T.: formal analysis, investigation, methodology, visualization, writing—original draft, writing—review and editing; S.B.: conceptualization, funding acquisition, writing—review and editing; S.G.: conceptualization, funding acquisition, investigation, methodology, writing—original draft, writing—review and editing.
All authors gave final approval for publication and agreed to be held accountable for the work performed therein.
Conflict of interest declaration
We declare that we have no competing interests.
Funding
S.G. and D.T. were supported by the US Army Research Office grant nos. W911NF-14-1-0637 and W911NF-18-1-0138 and the Office of Naval Research grant no. W911NF-17-1-0150, the National Institute for Mathematical and Biological Synthesis through NSF Award no. EF-0830858, and by the University of Tennessee, Knoxville. Part of the research supported from the US Department of Energy, Office of Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy, Advanced Manufacturing Office, under contract DE-AC05-00OR22725 with UT-Battelle, LLC. This manuscript has been authored by UT-Battelle, LLC under Contract no. DE-AC05- 00OR22725 with the U.S. Department of Energy. The United States Government retains and the publisher, by accepting the article for publication, acknowledges that the United States Government retains a non-exclusive, paid-up, irrevocable, world-wide license to publish or reproduce the published form of this manuscript, or allow others to do so, for United States Government purposes. The Department of Energy will provide public access to these results of federally sponsored research in accordance with the DOE Public Access Plan.
References
- 1.Abramovitz M. 1956. Resource and output trends in the United States since 1870. Am. Econ. Rev. 46, 5-23. [Google Scholar]
- 2.Solow R. 1957. Technical change and the aggregate production function. Rev. Econ. Stat. 39, 312-320. ( 10.2307/1926047) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 3.Currie T, Turchin P, Turner E, Gavrilets S. 2020. Duration of agriculture and distance from the steppe predict the evolution of large-scale human societies in Afro-Eurasia. Humanit. Soc. Sci. Commun. 7, 34. ( 10.1057/s41599-020-0516-2) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 4.Turchin P, Currie T, Turner EAL, Gavrilets S. 2013. War, space, and the evolution of Old World complex societies. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 109, 14 069-14 074. ( 10.1073/pnas.1201718109) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 5.Gong G, Keller W. 2003. Convergence and polarization in global income levels: a review of recent results on the role of international technology diffusion. Res. Policy 32, 1055-1079. ( 10.1016/S0048-7333(02)00136-1) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 6.Parente S, Prescott E. 1994. Barriers to technology adoption and development. J. Pol. Econ. 102, 298-321. ( 10.1086/261933) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 7.Comin D, Hobijn B. 2011. Technology diffusion and postwar growth. NBER Macroecon. Ann. 25, 209-246. ( 10.1086/657531) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 8.Baptista R. 1999. The diffusion of process innovations: a selective review. Int. J. Econ. Bus. 6, 107-129. ( 10.1080/13571519984359) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 9.Schumpeter J. 1934. The theory of economic development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar]
- 10.Peres R, Muller E, Mahajan V. 2010. Innovation diffusion and new product growth models: a critical review and research directions. Int. J. Res. Mark. 27, 91-106. ( 10.1016/j.ijresmar.2009.12.012) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 11.Saaksjarvi M. 2003. Consumer adoption of technological innovations. Eur. J. Innov. Manage. 6, 90-100. ( 10.1108/14601060310475246) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 12.Deffuant G, Huet S, Amblard F. 2005. An individual-based model of innovation diffusion mixing social value and individual benefit. AJS 110, 1041-1069. ( 10.1086/430220) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 13.Young H. 2006. The diffusion of innovations in social networks. In The economy as an evolving complex system III: current perspectives and future directions (eds Blume LE, Durlauf SN). Oxford Scholarship Online. ( 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195162592.001.0001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 14.Liebermann Y, Paroush J. 1982. Economic aspects of diffusion models. J. Econ. Bus. 34, 95-100. ( 10.1016/0148-6195(82)90021-2) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 15.Robertson T, Gatignon H. 1986. Competitive effects on technology diffusion. J. Mark. 50, 1-12. ( 10.1177/002224298605000301) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 16.Acemoglu D, Robinson J. 2000. Political losers as a barrier to economic development. Am. Econ. Rev. 90, 126-130. ( 10.1257/aer.90.2.126) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 17.Comin D, Hobijn B. 2009. Lobbies and technology diffusion. Rev. Econ. Stat. 91, 229-244. ( 10.1162/rest.91.2.229) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 18.Milner H. 2006. The digital divide: the role of political institutions in technology diffusion. Comp. Pol. Stud. 39, 176-199. ( 10.1177/0010414005282983) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 19.Chien-fei C, Xu X, Arpan L. 2017. Between the technology acceptance model and sustainable energy technology acceptance model: investigating smart meter acceptance in the United States. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 25, 93-104. ( 10.1016/j.erss.2016.12.011) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 20.Godin B. 2014. Invention, diffusion and linear models of innovation: the contribution of anthropology to a conceptual framework. J. Innov. Econ. Manage. 3, 11-37. ( 10.3917/jie.015.0011) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 21.Bass F. 1969. A new product growth for model consumer durables. Manage. Sci. 15, 215-227. ( 10.1287/mnsc.15.5.215) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 22.Kiesling E, Günther M, Stummer C, Wakolbinger L. 2012. Agent-based simulation of innovation diffusion: a review. Cent. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 20, 183-230. ( 10.1007/s10100-011-0210-y) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 23.Mahajan V, Muller E. 1979. Innovation diffusion and new product growth models in marketing. J. Mark. 43, 55-68. ( 10.1177/002224297904300407) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 24.Meade N, Islam T. 2006. Modelling and forecasting the diffusion of innovation – a 25-year review. Int. J. Forecast. 22, 519-545. ( 10.1016/j.ijforecast.2006.01.005) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 25.Chatterjee R, Eliashberg J. 1990. The innovation diffusion process in a heterogeneous population: a micromodeling approach. Manage. Sci. 36, 1057-1079. ( 10.1287/mnsc.36.9.1057) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 26.Bala V, Goyal S. 1998. Learning from neighbours. Rev. Econ. Stud. 65, 595-621. ( 10.1111/1467-937X.00059) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 27.Kreindler G, Young H. 2014. Rapid innovation diffusion in social networks. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 111, 10 881-10 888. ( 10.1073/pnas.1400842111) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 28.Martins A, Pereira C, Vicente R. 2009. An opinion dynamics model for the diffusion of innovations. Physica. A 388, 3225-3232. ( 10.1016/j.physa.2009.04.007) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 29.Montanari A, Saberi A. 2010. The spread of innovations in social networks. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 107, 20 196-20 201. ( 10.1073/pnas.1004098107) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 30.Goldenberg J, Han S, Lehmann D, Hong J. 2009. The role of hubs in the adoption process. J. Mark. 73, 1-13. ( 10.1509/jmkg.73.2.1) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 31.Desmarchelier B, Fang E. 2016. National culture and innovation diffusion: exploratory insights from agent-based modeling. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 105, 121-128. ( 10.1016/j.techfore.2016.01.018) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 32.Aral S, Walker D. 2011. Creating social contagion through viral product design: a randomized trial of peer influence in networks. Manage. Sci. 57, 1623-1639. ( 10.1287/mnsc.1110.1421) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 33.Iyengar R, Van den Bulte C, Valente TW. 2011. Opinion leadership and social contagion in new product diffusion. Mark. Sci. 30, 195-212. ( 10.1287/mksc.1100.0566) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 34.Bhojvaid V, Jeuland M, Kar A, Lewis JJ, Pattanayak SK, Ramanathan N, Ramanathan V, Rehman IH. 2014. How do people in rural India perceive improved stoves and clean fuel? Evidence from Uttar Pradesh and Uttarakhand. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 11, 1341-1358. ( 10.3390/ijerph110201341) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 35.Agarwal B. 1983. Diffusion of rural innovations: some analytical issues and the case of wood-burning stoves. World Dev. 11, 359-376. ( 10.1016/0305-750X(83)90047-5) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 36.Misra K, et al. 1975. Safe water in rural areas. An experiment in promoting community participation in India. Int. J. Health Educ. 18, 53-59. [Google Scholar]
- 37.Park S. 2004. Quantitative analysis of network externalities in competing technologies: the VCR case. Rev. Econ. Stat. 86, 937-945. ( 10.1162/0034653043125275) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 38.Merton RK. 1948. The self fulfilling prophecy. Antioch Rev. 8, 173-190. ( 10.2307/4609267) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 39.Barzilai-Nahon K, Barzilai G. 2005. Cultured technology: the internet and religious fundamentalism. Inf. Soc. 21, 25-40. ( 10.1080/01972240590895892) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 40.Kleijnen M, Wetzels M, De Ruyter K. 2004. Consumer acceptance of wireless finance. J. Financ. Ser. Mark. 8, 206-217. ( 10.1057/palgrave.fsm.4770120) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 41.Loch K, Straub D, Kamel S. 2003. Diffusing the Internet in the Arab world: the role of social norms and technological culturation. IEEE Trans. Eng. Manage. 50, 45-63. ( 10.1109/TEM.2002.808257) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 42.Sawang S, Sun Y, Salim S. 2014. It’s not only what I think but what they think! The moderating effect of social norms. Comput. Educ. 76, 182-189. ( 10.1016/j.compedu.2014.03.017) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 43.Webster J, Trevino L. 1995. Rational and social theories as complementary explanations of communication media choices: two policy-capturing studies. Acad. Manage. J. 38, 1544-1572. ( 10.5465/256843) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 44.Bicchieri C. 2006. The grammar of society: the nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- 45.Cialdini R, Reno R, Kallgren C. 1990. A focus theory of normative conduct: recycling the concept of norms to reduce littering in public places. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 58, 1015-1026. ( 10.1037/0022-3514.58.6.1015) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 46.Kallgren C, Reno R, Cialdini R. 2000. A focus theory of normative conduct: when norms do and do not affect behavior. Pers. Soc. Psychol. Bull. 26, 1002-1012. ( 10.1177/01461672002610009) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 47.Reno R, Cialdini R, Kallgren C. 1993. The transsituational influence of social norms. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 64, 104-112. ( 10.1037/0022-3514.64.1.104) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 48.Gavrilets S. 2020. The dynamics of injunctive social norms. Evol. Hum. Sci. 2, e60. ( 10.1017/ehs.2020.58) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 49.Ushchev P, Zenou Y. 2017. Technology adoption and social norms. See https://scholar.google.com/scholar?hl=ru&as_sdt=0%2C43&q=Ushchev%2C+P.+and+Zenou%2C+Y.+%282017%29.+Technology+adoption+and+social+norms&btnG=.
- 50.Young H. 2011. The dynamics of social innovations. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 108, 21 285-21 291. ( 10.1073/pnas.1100973108) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 51.Le Coent P, Preget R, Thoyer S. 2018. Do farmers follow the herd? The influence of social norms in the participation to agri-environmental schemes. HAL Open Science. See https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-01936004/document. [Google Scholar]
- 52.Festinger L. 1962. Cognitive dissonance. Sci. Am. 207, 93-106. ( 10.1038/scientificamerican1062-93) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 53.McGrath A. 2017. Dealing with dissonance: a review of cognitive dissonance reduction. Soc. Personal Psychol. Compass 11, e12362. ( 10.1111/spc3.12362) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 54.Marikyan D, Papagiannidis S, Alamanos E. 2020. Cognitive dissonance in technology adoption: a study of smart home users. Inf. Syst. Front., 1-23. ( 10.1007/s10796-020-10042-3) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 55.Park I, Cho J, Rao H. 2015. The dynamics of pre-and post-purchase service and consumer evaluation of online retailers: a comparative analysis of dissonance and disconfirmation models. Decis. Sci. 46, 1109-1140. ( 10.1111/deci.12176) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 56.Venkatesh V, Goyal S. 2010. Expectation disconfirmation and technology adoption: polynomial modeling and response surface analysis. MIS Q. 34, 281-303. ( 10.2307/20721428) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 57.Briley DA, Morris MW, Simonson I. 2000. Reasons as carriers of culture: dynamic versus dispositional models of cultural influence on decision making. J. Consum. Res. 27, 157-178. ( 10.1086/314318) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 58.Chang LJ, Sanfey AG. 2013. Great expectations: neural computations underlying the use of social norms in decision-making. Soc. Cogn. Affect. Neurosci. 8, 277-284. ( 10.1093/scan/nsr094) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 59.Guess CD. 2004. Decision making in individualistic and collectivistic cultures. Online Read. Psychol. Cult. 4, 1-18. [Google Scholar]
- 60.Harmon-Jones E, Harmon-Jones C. 2002. Testing the action-based model of cognitive dissonance: the effect of action orientation on postdecisional attitudes. Pers. Soc. Psychol. Bull. 28, 711-723. ( 10.1177/0146167202289001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 61.Jarcho JM, Berkman ET, Lieberman MD. 2011. The neural basis of rationalization: cognitive dissonance reduction during decision-making. Soc. Cogn. Affect. Neurosci. 6, 460-467. ( 10.1093/scan/nsq054) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 62.Melnyk V, van Herpen E, Trijp H. 2010. The influence of social norms in consumer decision making: a meta-analysis. ACR North Am. Adv. 37, 463-464. ( 10.1027/2151-2604/a000352) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 63.Sanfey AG, Stallen M, Chang LJ. 2014. Norms and expectations in social decision-making. Trends Cogn. Sci. 18, 172-174. ( 10.1016/j.tics.2014.01.011) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 64.Calabuig V, Olcina G, Panebianco F. 2017. The dynamics of personal norms and the determinants of cultural homogeneity. Ration. Soc. 29, 322-354. ( 10.1177/1043463117717233) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 65.Calabuig V, Olcina G, Panebianco F. 2018. Culture and team production. J. Econ. Behav. Org. 149, 32-45. ( 10.1016/j.jebo.2018.03.004) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 66.Kuran T. 1989. Sparks and prairie fires: a theory of unanticipated political revolution. Public Choice 61, 41-74. ( 10.1007/BF00116762) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 67.Kuran T, Sandholm WH. 2008. Cultural integration and its discontents. Rev. Econ. Stud. 75, 201-228. ( 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2007.00469.x) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 68.Rabin M. 1994. Cognitive dissonance and social change. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 24, 177-194. ( 10.1016/0167-2681(94)90066-3) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 69.Zino L, Ye M, Cao M. 2020. A two-layer model for coevolving opinion dynamics and collective decision-making in complex social systems. Chaos 20, 083107. ( 10.1063/5.0004787) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 70.Centola D, Willer R, Macy M. 2005. The emperor’s dilemma: a computational model of self-enforcing norms. AJS 110, 1009-1040. ( 10.1086/427321) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 71.Friedkin NE, Proskurnikov AV, Tempo R, Parsegov SE. 2016. Network science on belief system dynamics under logic constraints. Science 354, 321-326. ( 10.1126/science.aag2624) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 72.Redner S. 2019. Reality inspired voter models: a mini-review. C. R. Phys. 20, 275-292. ( 10.1016/j.crhy.2019.05.004) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 73.Watts DJ. 2002. A simple model of global cascades on random networks. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 99, 5766-5771. ( 10.1073/pnas.082090499) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 74.Azar O. 2004. What sustains social norms and how they evolve? The case of tipping. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 54, 49-64. ( 10.1016/j.jebo.2003.06.001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 75.Azar OH. 2008. Evolution of social norms with heterogeneous preferences: a general model and an application to the academic review process. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 65, 420-435. ( 10.1016/j.jebo.2006.03.006) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 76.Gavrilets S. 2021. Coevolution of actions, personal norms and beliefs about others in social dilemmas. Evol. Hum. Sci. 3, e44. ( 10.1017/ehs.2021.40) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 77.Gavrilets S, Richerson J. 2017. Collective action and the evolution of social norm internalization. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 114, 6068-6073. ( 10.1073/pnas.1703857114) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 78.Tverskoi D, Guido A, Andrighetto G, Sanchez A, Gavrilets S. 2021. Disentangling material, social, and cognitive determinants of human behavior and beliefs. SocArXiv. ( 10.31235/osf.io/z5m9h) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 79.Argote L, Epple D. 1990. Learning curves in manufacturing. Science 247, 920-924. ( 10.1126/science.247.4945.920) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 80.Arrow K. 1962. The economic implications of learning by doing. Rev. Econ. Stud. 29, 155-173. ( 10.2307/2295952) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 81.Fudenberg D, Tirole J. 1983. Learning-by-doing and market performance. Bell J. Econ. 14, 522-530. ( 10.2307/3003653) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 82.Lin Y, Han X, Wang B. 2014. Dynamics of human innovative behaviors. Physica A 394, 74-81. ( 10.1016/j.physa.2013.09.039) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 83.Young H. 2009. Innovation diffusion in heterogeneous populations: contagion, social influence, and social learning. Am. Econ. Rev. 99, 1899-1924. ( 10.1257/aer.99.5.1899) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 84.Geroski P. 2000. Models of technology diffusion. Res. Policy 29, 603-625. ( 10.1016/S0048-7333(99)00092-X) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 85.Anzanello M, Fogliatto F. 2011. Learning curve models and applications: literature review and research directions. Int. J. Ind. Ergon. 41, 573-583. ( 10.1016/j.ergon.2011.05.001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 86.Davidovitch L, Parush A, Shtub A. 2008. Simulation-based learning: the learning–forgetting–relearning process and impact of learning history. Comput. Educ. 50, 866-880. ( 10.1016/j.compedu.2006.09.003) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 87.Eden C, Williams T, Ackermann F. 1998. Dismantling the learning curve: the role of disruptions on the planning of development projects. Int. J. Prod. Manage. 16, 131-138. ( 10.1016/S0263-7863(97)00053-7) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 88.Jaber M, Bonney M. 1996. Production breaks and the learning curve: the forgetting phenomenon. Appl. Math. Modell. 20, 162-169. ( 10.1016/0307-904X(95)00157-F) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 89.Jaber M, Bonney M. 2007. Economic manufacture quantity (EMQ) model with lot-size dependent learning and forgetting rates. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 108, 359-367. ( 10.1016/j.ijpe.2006.12.020) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 90.Jaber M, Kher H. 2004. Variant versus invariant time to total forgetting: the learn–forget curve model revisited. Comput. Ind. Eng. 46, 697-705. ( 10.1016/j.cie.2004.05.006) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 91.Yelle L. 1979. The learning curve: historical review and comprehensive survey. Decis. Sci. 10, 302-328. ( 10.1111/j.1540-5915.1979.tb00026.x) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 92.Argote L. 1993. Group and organizational learning curves: individual, system and environmental components. Br. J. Soc. Psychol. 32, 31-51. ( 10.1111/j.2044-8309.1993.tb00984.x) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 93.Fioretti G. 2007. The organizational learning curve. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 177, 1375-1384. ( 10.1016/j.ejor.2005.04.009) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 94.Knecht G. 1974. Costing, technological growth and generalized learning curves. Oper. Res. Q. 25, 487-491. ( 10.1057/jors.1974.82) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 95.Towill D. 1990. Forecasting learning curves. Int. J. Forecast. 6, 25-38. ( 10.1016/0169-2070(90)90095-S) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 96.Wright T. 1936. Factors affecting the cost of airplanes. J. Aeronaut. Sci. 3, 122-128. ( 10.2514/8.155) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 97.Goeree JK, Holt CA, Palfrey TR. 2016. Quantal response equilibrium. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
- 98.Akerlof G. 1980. A theory of social custom, of which unemployment may be one consequence. Q. J. Econ. 94, 749-775. ( 10.2307/1885667) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 99.Bernheim B. 1994. A theory of conformity. J. Pol. Econ. 102, 841-877. ( 10.1086/261957) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 100.Górges L, Nosenzo D. 2020. Measuring social norms in economics: why it is important and how it is done. Anal. Kritik 42, 285-311. ( 10.1515/auk-2020-0012) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 101.Loewenstein G, Molnar A. 2018. The renaissance of belief-based utility in economics. Nat. Hum. Behav. 2, 166-167. ( 10.1038/s41562-018-0301-z) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 102.Nyborg K. 2018. Social norms and the environment. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 10, 405-423. ( 10.1146/annurev-resource-100517-023232) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 103.Gavrilets S, Shrestha M. 2021. Evolving institutions for collective action by selective imitation and self-interested design. Evol. Hum. Behav. 42, 1-11. ( 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2020.05.007) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 104.Perry L, Gavrilets S. 2020. Foresight in a game of leadership. Soc. Res. 10, 1-10. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 105.Perry L, Shrestha M, Vose M, Gavrilets S. 2018. Collective action problem in heterogeneous groups with punishment and foresight. J. Stat. Phys. 172, 293-312. ( 10.1007/s10955-018-2012-2) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 106.Szpunar KK, Spreng RN, Schactera DL. 2014. A taxonomy of prospection: introducing an organizational framework for future-oriented cognition. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 111, 18 414-18 421. ( 10.1073/pnas.1417144111) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 107.Berns GS, Laibson D, Loewenstein G. 2007. Intertemporal choice—toward an integrative framework. Trends Cogn. Sci. 11, 482-488. ( 10.1016/j.tics.2007.08.011) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 108.Frederick S, Loewenstein G, O’Donoghue T. 2002. Time discounting and time preference: a critical review. J. Econ. Lit. 40, 351-401. ( 10.1257/jel.40.2.351) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 109.Festinger L. 1957. A theory of cognitive dissonance, vol. 2. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. [Google Scholar]
- 110.Song G, Ma Q, Wu F, Li L. 2012. The psychological explanation of conformity. Soc. Behav. Pers.: Int. J. 40, 1365-1372. ( 10.2224/sbp.2012.40.8.1365) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 111.Cialdini RB, Goldstein NJ. 2004. Social influence: compliance and conformity. Annu. Rev. Psychol. 55, 591-621. ( 10.1146/annurev.psych.55.090902.142015) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 112.Akerlof GA. 1997. Social distance and social decisions. Econometrica 65, 1005-1027. ( 10.2307/2171877) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 113.Fehr E, Schurtenberger I. 2018. Normative foundations of human cooperation. Nat. Hum. Behav. 2, 458-468. ( 10.1038/s41562-018-0385-5) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 114.Fershtman C, Weiss Y. 1998. Social rewards, externalities and stable preferences. J. Public Econ. 70, 53-73. ( 10.1016/S0047-2727(98)00060-7) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 115.Kandel E, Lazear EP. 1992. Peer pressure and partnerships. J. Polit. Econ. 100, 801-817. ( 10.1086/261840) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 116.Galesic M, Stein DL. 2019. Statistical physics models of belief dynamics: theory and empirical tests. Physica A 519, 275-294. ( 10.1016/j.physa.2018.12.011) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 117.Gavrilets YN. 2003. Stochastic modeling of between-group social interactions. Econ. Math. Methods 39, 106-116. [in Russian.] [Google Scholar]
- 118.Kashima Y, Perfors A, Ferdinand V, Pattenden E. 2021. Ideology, communication and polarization. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 376, 20200133. ( 10.1098/rstb.2020.0133) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 119.De Vita J. 1979. Niche separation and the broken-stick model. Am. Nat. 114, 171-178. ( 10.1086/283466) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 120.MacArthur R. 1957. On the relative abundance of bird species. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 43, 293-295. ( 10.1073/pnas.43.3.293) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 121.Stoneman P, Diederen P. 1994. Technology diffusion and public policy. Econ. J. 104, 918-930. ( 10.2307/2234987) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 122.Heine S, Lehman D. 1997. Culture, dissonance, and self-affirmation. Pers. Soc. Psychol. Bull. 23, 389-400. ( 10.1177/0146167297234005) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 123.Henrich J. 2015. The secret of our success. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
- 124.Richerson PJ, Gavrilets S, de Waal FBM. 2021. Modern theories of human evolution foreshadowed by Darwin’s Descent of Man. Science 372, eaba3776. ( 10.1126/science.aba3776) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 125.Granovetter M. 1978. Threshold models of collective behavior. AJS 83, 1420-1443. [Google Scholar]
- 126.Rashevsky N. 1949. Mathematical biology of social behavior. III. Bull. Math. Biol. 11, 255-271. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 127.Rashevsky N. 1951. Mathematical biology of social behavior. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. [Google Scholar]
- 128.Rashevsky N. 1965. A note on imitative behavior. Bull. Math. Biophys. 27, 311-313. ( 10.1007/BF02478408) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 129.Rashevsky N. 1965. On imitative behavior. Bull. Math. Biophys. 27, 175-185. ( 10.1007/BF02498773) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 130.Davis R, Campbell R, Hildon Z, Hobbs L, Michie S. 2015. Theories of behaviour and behaviour change across the social and behavioural sciences: a scoping review. Health Psychol. Rev. 9, 323-344. ( 10.1080/17437199.2014.941722) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 131.Martins A. 2008. Continuous opinions and discrete actions in opinion dynamics problems. Int. J. Mod. Phys. C 19, 617-624. ( 10.1142/S0129183108012339) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 132.Martins A. 2008. Mobility and social network effects on extremist opinions. Phys. Rev. E 78, 036104. ( 10.1103/PhysRevE.78.036104) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 133.Jager W, Janssen M, De Vries H, De Greef J, Vlek C. 2000. Behaviour in commons dilemmas: Homo economicus and Homo psychologicus in an ecological-economic model. Ecol. Econ. 35, 357-379. ( 10.1016/S0921-8009(00)00220-2) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 134.Schwarz N, Ernst A. 2009. Agent-based modeling of the diffusion of environmental innovations—an empirical approach. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 76, 497-511. ( 10.1016/j.techfore.2008.03.024) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 135.Kaufmann P, Stagl S, Franks D. 2009. Simulating the diffusion of organic farming practices in two New EU Member States. Ecol. Econ. 68, 2580-2593. ( 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2009.04.001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 136.Zhang T, Nuttall W. 2011. Evaluating government’s policies on promoting smart metering diffusion in retail electricity markets via agent-based simulation. J. Prod. Innov. Manage. 28, 169-186. ( 10.1111/j.1540-5885.2011.00790.x) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 137.Ajzen I. 1991. The theory of planned behavior. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 50, 179-211. ( 10.1016/0749-5978(91)90020-T) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 138.Bakar MFA, Talukder M, Quazi A, Khan I. 2020. Adoption of sustainable technology in the Malaysian SMEs sector: does the role of government matter? Information 11, 215. ( 10.3390/info11040215) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 139.Delre S, Jager W, Janssen M. 2007. Diffusion dynamics in small-world networks with heterogeneous consumers. Comput. Math. Organ. Theory 13, 185-202. ( 10.1007/s10588-006-9007-2) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 140.Dodson J Jr, Muller E. 1978. Models of new product diffusion through advertising and word-of-mouth. Manage. Sci. 24, 1568-1578. ( 10.1287/mnsc.24.15.1568) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 141.Goldenberg J, Libai B, Muller E. 2001. Talk of the network: a complex systems look at the underlying process of word-of-mouth. Mark. Lett. 12, 211-223. ( 10.1023/A:1011122126881) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 142.Goldenberg J, Libai B, Moldovan S, Muller E. 2007. The NPV of bad news. Int. J. Res. Mark. 24, 186-200. ( 10.1016/j.ijresmar.2007.02.003) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 143.Bernays E. 1928. Propaganda. Brooklyn, NY: Ig Publishing. [Google Scholar]
- 144.Jowett GS, O’Donnell V. 2018. Propaganda & persuasion. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. [Google Scholar]
- 145.Atwood C, Griffith M, Harwell L, Schlienger E, Ensz M, Smugeresky J, Romero T, Greene D, Reckaway D. 1998. Laser engineered net shaping (lensTM): a tool for direct fabrication of metal parts. In Int. Cong. on Applications of Lasers & Electro-Optics, vol. 1998, pp. E1–E7. Laser Institute of America.
- 146.Kobryn PA, Semiatin SL. 2001. Mechanical properties of laser-deposited Ti-6Al-4V. In Int. Solid Freeform Fabrication Symp., pp. 179–186. See http://utw10945.utweb.utexas.edu/Manuscripts/2001/2001-21-Kobryn.pdf.
- 147.Gibson I, Rosen D, Stucker B. 2015. Additive manufacturing technologies: 3D printing, rapid prototyping and direct digital manufacturing. 2nd edn. Berlin, Germany: Springer. [Google Scholar]
- 148.The White House Office of the Press Secretary. 2011. President Obama launches advanced manufacturing partnership. See https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/the-press-office/2011/06/24/president-obama-launches-advanced-manufacturing-partnership.
- 149.The White House Office of the Press Secretary. 2012. We can’t wait: Obama administration announces new public-private partnership to support. See https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/the-press-office/2012/08/16/we-can-t-wait-obama-administration-announces-new-public-private-partners.
- 150.DebRoy T, et al. 2018. Additive manufacturing of metallic components—process, structure and properties. Prog. Mater. Sci. 92, 112-224. ( 10.1016/j.pmatsci.2017.10.001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 151.Kitayama S, Snibbe A, Markus H, Suzuki T. 2004. Is there any ‘free’ choice? Self and dissonance in two cultures. Psychol. Sci. 15, 527-533. ( 10.1111/j.0956-7976.2004.00714.x) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 152.Snibbe A, Markus H. 2005. You can’t always get what you want: educational attainment, agency, and choice. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 88, 703-720. ( 10.1037/0022-3514.88.4.703) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 153.Yates J, de Oliveira S. 2016. Culture and decision making. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process 136, 106-118. ( 10.1016/j.obhdp.2016.05.003) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 154.Rieger MO, Wang M, Hens T. 2021. Universal time preference. PLoS ONE 16, e0245692. ( 10.1371/journal.pone.0245692) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 155.Strathman A, Gleicher F, Boninger D, Edwards C. 1994. The consideration of future consequences: weighing immediate and distant outcomes of behavior. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 66, 742-752. ( 10.1037/0022-3514.66.4.742) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 156.Tan C, Johnson R. 1996. To wait or not to wait: the influence of culture on discounting behavior. In Perspectives on judgment and decision making (ed. Loke W), pp. 297-305. Lanham, MD: Scarecrow Press. [Google Scholar]
- 157.Du W, Green L, Myerson J. 2002. Cross-cultural comparisons on discounting delayed and probabilistic rewards. Psychol. Rec. 52, 479-492. ( 10.1007/BF03395199) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 158.Mahajna A, Benzion U, Bogaire R, Shavit T. 2008. Subjective discount rates among Israeli Arabs and Israeli Jews. J. Socio-Econ. 37, 2513-2522. ( 10.1016/j.socec.2007.11.003) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 159.Wang M, Rieger M, Hens T. 2016. How time preferences differ: evidence from 53 countries. J. Econ. Psychol. 52, 115-135. ( 10.1016/j.joep.2015.12.001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 160.Fu P, et al. 2004. The impact of societal cultural values and individual social beliefs on the perceived effectiveness of managerial influence strategies: a meso approach. J. Int. Bus. Stud. 35, 284-305. ( 10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400090) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 161.Venaik S, Zhu Y, Brewer P. 2013. Looking into the future: Hofstede long term orientation versus GLOBE future orientation. Cross Cult. Manage.: Int. J. 20, 361-385. ( 10.1108/CCM-02-2012-0014) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 162.Tian M, Deng P, Zhang Y, Salmador M. 2018. How does culture influence innovation? A systematic literature review. Manage. Decis. 56, 1088-1107. ( 10.1108/MD-05-2017-0462) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 163.Naor M, Linderman K, Schroeder R. 2010. The globalization of operations in Eastern and Western countries: unpacking the relationship between national and organizational culture and its impact on manufacturing performance. J. Oper. Manage. 28, 194-205. ( 10.1016/j.jom.2009.11.001) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 164.Chua R, Huang K, Jin M. 2019. Mapping cultural tightness and its links to innovation, urbanization, and happiness across 31 provinces in China. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 116, 6720-6725. ( 10.1073/pnas.1815723116) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 165.He M, Lee J. 2020. Social culture and innovation diffusion: a theoretically founded agent-based model. J. Evol. Econ. 30, 1-41. ( 10.1007/s00191-020-00662-y) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 166.Gelfand M, Nishii L, Raver J. 2006. On the nature and importance of cultural tightness-looseness. J. Appl. Psychol. 91, 1225-1244. ( 10.1037/0021-9010.91.6.1225) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 167.Gelfand M, Raver J, Nishii L, Leslie L, Lun J, Lim B. 2011. Differences between tight and loose cultures: a 33-nation study. Science 332, 1100-1104. ( 10.1126/science.1197754) [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 168.Harrington J, Gelfand M. 2014. Tightness-looseness across the 50 United States. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 111, 7990-7995. ( 10.1073/pnas.1317937111) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 169.Mathukrishna M, Henrich J. 2016. Innovation in the collective brain. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 371, 20150192. ( 10.1098/rstb.2015.0192) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 170.Ehrlich P, Levin S. 2005. The evolution of norms. PLoS Biol. 3, e194. ( 10.1371/journal.pbio.0030194) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 171.Haynes C, Luck M, McBurney P, Mahmoud S, Vítek T, Miles S. 2017. Engineering the emergence of norms: a review. Knowl. Eng. Rev. 32, 1-31. ( 10.1017/S0269888917000169) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 172.Prentice D. 2018. Intervening to change social norms: when does it work? Soc. Res. 85, 115-139. ( 10.1353/sor.2018.0007) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 173.Delre S, Jager W, Bijmolt T, Janssen M. 2010. Will it spread or not? The effects of social influences and network topology on innovation diffusion. J. Product. Innov. Manage. 27, 267-282. ( 10.1111/j.1540-5885.2010.00714.x) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 174.Gavrilets S, Auerbach J, van Vugt M. 2016. Convergence to consensus in heterogeneous groups and the emergence of informal leadership. Sci. Rep. 6, 29704. ( 10.1038/srep29704) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 175.Moldovan S, Goldenberg J. 2004. Cellular automata modeling of resistance to innovations: effects and solutions. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 71, 425-442. ( 10.1016/S0040-1625(03)00026-X) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 176.Valente T, Davis R. 1999. Accelerating the diffusion of innovations using opinion leaders. Ann. Am. Acad. Pol. Soc. Sci. 566, 55-67. ( 10.1177/000271629956600105) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 177.Delre S, Jager W, Bijmolt T, Janssen M. 2007. Targeting and timing promotional activities: an agent-based model for the takeoff of new products. J. Bus. Res. 60, 826-835. ( 10.1016/j.jbusres.2007.02.002) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 178.Coccia M. 2014. Socio-cultural origins of the patterns of technological innovation: what is the likely interaction among religious culture, religious plurality and innovation? Towards a theory of socio-cultural drivers of the patterns of technological innovation. Technol. Soc. 36, 13-25. ( 10.1016/j.techsoc.2013.11.002) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 179.Borgers T, Sarin R. 1997. Learning through reinforcement and replicator dynamics. J. Econ. Theory 77, 1-14. ( 10.1006/jeth.1997.2319) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 180.Hirschman E. 1980. Innovativeness, novelty seeking, and consumer creativity. J. Consum. Res. 7, 283-295. ( 10.1086/208816) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 181.Schweizer T. 2006. The psychology of novelty-seeking, creativity and innovation: neurocognitive aspects within a work-psychological perspective. Creat. Innov. Manage. 15, 164-172. ( 10.1111/j.1467-8691.2006.00383.x) [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 182.Tverskoi D, Babu S, Gavrilets S. 2022. The spread of technological innovations: effects of psychology, culture and policy interventions. Zenodo. ( 10.5281/zenodo.5715314) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
- 183.Tverskoi D, Babu S, Gavrilets S. 2022. The spread of technological innovations: effects of psychology, culture and policy interventions. FigShare. ( 10.6084/m9.figshare.c.6035739) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
Associated Data
This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.
Data Citations
- Tverskoi D, Babu S, Gavrilets S. 2022. The spread of technological innovations: effects of psychology, culture and policy interventions. Zenodo. ( 10.5281/zenodo.5715314) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
- Tverskoi D, Babu S, Gavrilets S. 2022. The spread of technological innovations: effects of psychology, culture and policy interventions. FigShare. ( 10.6084/m9.figshare.c.6035739) [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
Data Availability Statement
The simulations were performed in MATLAB (Version R2019b). Data and relevant code for this research work are stored in GitHub: https://github.com/dtverskoi/The-spread-of-technological-innovations-effects-of-psychology-culture-and-policy-interventions and have been archived within the Zenodo repository: https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.5715314 [182].
Electronic supplementary material is available online [183].