Skip to main content
Evolution, Medicine, and Public Health logoLink to Evolution, Medicine, and Public Health
. 2022 Aug 4;10(1):339–351. doi: 10.1093/emph/eoac029

Girls start life on an uneven playing field

Evidence from lowland rural Nepal

Akanksha A Marphatia 1,2, Naomi S Saville 3, Dharma S Manandhar 4, Mario Cortina-Borja 5, Alice M Reid 6,2, Jonathan C K Wells 7,✉,2
PMCID: PMC9384836  PMID: 35990287

Abstract

Background and objectives

Evolutionary research on the sex ratio at birth (SRB) has focused on explaining variability within and between populations, and whether parental fitness is maximized by producing daughters or sons. We tested predictors of SRB in a low-income setting, to understand whether girls differ from boys in their likelihood of being born into families with the capacity to invest in them, which has implications for their future health and fitness.

Methodology

We used data from a cluster randomized control trial from lowland rural Nepal (16 115 mother-child dyads). We applied principal component analysis to extract two composite indices reflecting maternal socio-economic and reproductive (parity, age) capital. We fitted mixed-effects logistic regression models to estimate odds ratios of having a girl in association with these individual factors and indices.

Results

The SRB was 112. Compared to the global reference SRB (105), there were seven missing girls per 100 boys. Uneducated, early-marrying, poorer and shorter mothers were more likely to give birth to girls. Analysing composite maternal indices, lower socio-economic and reproductive capital were independently associated with a greater likelihood of having a girl.

Conclusions and implications

In this population, girls start life facing composite disadvantages, being more likely than boys to be born to mothers with lower socio-economic status and reproductive capital. Both physiological and behavioural mechanisms may contribute to these epidemiological associations. Differential early exposure by sex to maternal factors may underpin intergenerational cycles of gender inequality, mediated by developmental trajectory, education and socio-economic status.

INTRODUCTION

Globally, the average sex ratio at birth (SRB) is 107 males per 100 female births [1]. However, this is skewed by higher SRBs in countries with strong son preferences and access to pre-natal sex selection. For these reasons, the United Nations (UN) uses 105:100 as the ‘expected biological sex ratio’ at birth [2] and we follow this approach in our analysis described below. The slight male bias has been attributed to sex differences in the pattern of mortality during pregnancy: the sex ratio appears equal at conception, but overall, female mortality is slightly higher than male mortality over the early stages of gestation, resulting in a slight excess of males by birth, despite higher male mortality towards the end of gestation and during the process of birth [3]. In South Asia, more boys than girls are born each year compared to UN’s expected SRB. For example, data from 2017 indicate an SRB of 110:100 for India and 107:100 for Nepal, where our study is based [4], with the UN calculating similar values [1]. However, the SRB within Nepal also varies substantially by region [5].

To explain SRB variability within and between populations, researchers have investigated whether biological traits or parental behaviour patterns can help predict whether individual women are more likely to produce sons or daughters. A systematic review identified 10 factors influencing the SRB, ranging from individual level biological factors, such as maternal-stress and coital rates, to environment-related factors, such as exposure to air pollution from incinerators, access to sex-determination technology and abortion of female foetuses [6]. To frame such analyses, many have drawn explicitly on evolutionary theory, to investigate whether SRB variability may have an adaptive element.

For example, the well-known Trivers–Willard hypothesis [7] proposed that since in mammals reproductive success tends to be more variable in adult males than females, and since adult phenotype bears an imprint of maternal investment in early life, mothers would maximize their fitness if they were more likely to produce sons when in good condition, and daughters if not in good condition. This hypothesis has attracted much attention, both in non-human mammals and humans. There is growing theoretical [8] and mechanistic [9, 10] support for the notion that components of maternal nutritional status can influence the SRB, however, support specifically for the Trivers–Willard hypothesis of SRB variability in humans remains weak and inconsistent [11–14].

An alternative approach focuses less on individual maternal traits, and more on ecological factors impacting the whole population. According to the ‘frail male’ hypothesis, males are considered more vulnerable to external stresses, resulting in changes in the SRB of the population over time in association with varying ecological conditions [15]. In the USA, for example, fewer boys were born alive during the Spanish Flu epidemic and the Great Depression than at other times, whereas individual-level markers of maternal condition did not predict the SRB [15]. Similarly, a study from Nepal found that exposure to adverse conditions during pregnancy, such as civil conflict, were associated with higher mortality of sons in utero and hence a higher likelihood of having a daughter [16].

At a broader level, any family factors that contribute to SRB variability merit attention through the lens of gender inequality [17, 18]. If maternal characteristics shape the likelihood of having sons versus daughters, then the two sexes may on average not be born into identical family environments. Moreover, more gender-unequal societies may have a stronger son preference, as found in a study comparing two villages with different levels of women’s autonomy and fertility in Nepal [19]. These issues have attracted relatively little attention in evolutionary studies which have focused on the implications of the SRB for the reproductive fitness of the mother, rather than the direct implications for the offspring.

Our study therefore aims to analyse predictors of the SRB in a low-income setting, in order to understand whether girls and boys start life equally distributed across a population, or whether they are differentially likely to cluster in association with socio-economic, demographic or biological factors that may shape the capacity for families to invest in them. Given compelling evidence that experience in early life has substantial implications for adult health, human capital and reproductive fitness [20–23], the notion that girls and boys might on average pass through different societal and biological ‘niches’ in early life merits attention. By going beyond the Trivers–Willard hypothesis, we aim to offer a more comprehensive perspective on gender inequality and gain new insight into its intergenerational transmission.

At the level of society, there may be several reasons why the SRB is actively skewed towards a male bias, reflecting socio-economic dynamics. For example, in South Asian patrilineal societies where the economic contributions of men are important in maintaining parents in older age, and the household over time, families prioritize investment in raising sons [24]. Moreover, in some societies including the context of our study, the absolute ‘cost’ of raising girls increases through life stages not only for basic care, food and education but also for dowry payments at marriage [25]. In patrilocal societies, investment in girls is considered to be ‘lost’ to the natal family because at marriage a girl moves to her husband’s home, whereas a boy is generally expected to remain in the natal home with his new wife [26]. Analysing data across and within 108 countries, Ebenstein found a strong correlation between a high SRB and countries practicing patrilocality, where a high proportion of parents co-reside with sons and benefit from elder age care from their daughters-in-law, rather than daughters [27]. In the same countries, intensive agriculture is widely practiced, which increases the value of land and hence of its inheritance through the male line [27].

To satisfy any preference for having sons, there may be active and deliberate practices to selectively abort female foetuses using sex-determination technology. In Nepal, direct evidence for this practice is sparse, due to it being illegal and punishable by imprisonment. Nevertheless, it is apparent that the SRB became more skewed after the legalization of abortion in 2002 [28]. Indirect evidence also comes from the finding that approximately one-quarter of the national population lives in urban regions where the SRB is >110, suggesting that up to 10% of girls may be missing in some urban localities [5].

The practice of sex-selective abortion seems to become more prominent for later births [29]. Since males have higher infant and child mortality rates, parents with a strong son preference may want to have more boys to increase the chance of having surviving sons [30]. Several studies have reported that families are more likely to have a boy as the second or third child, if the first- and second-born children were girls [31–34]. Conversely, a national survey of Nepal suggests that since the likelihood of having a son is lower as fertility rates decline, sex-selective abortion is increasingly used by wealthier and more educated groups [5].

Beyond efforts to influence the sex of children born into the family, parents may also invest differently in sons versus daughters after they have been born, in relation to outcomes such as health and education. The extent to which this occurs appears to vary between settings. In the USA, wealthier families do not appear to invest more in sons than daughters [35], whereas Greece and Spain have skewed sex ratios at birth and throughout infancy and childhood [36, 37]. In low-income settings, and especially in South Asia, son-preference is well described [24, 38, 39], and follows the same logic as that described for artificial sex selection in utero described above. In this context, gender inequality may be perpetuated after birth. For example, in Nepal, parents invest more in educating sons than daughters, as shown by lower girls’ secondary educational attainment [40, 41]. Whilst during childhood and adolescence boys appear to be more stunted and thinner than girls in Nepal, once girls marry, they tend to eat last and less at meals they prepare in their marital homes, which contributes to their undernutrition [42, 43]. Another study in South Asian countries including Nepal found that son preference interacted with sibling composition with multiple brothers and sisters increasing girls’ risk for acute (wasting) and chronic (stunting/underweight) malnutrition [44].

Using data from a cluster randomized control trial of 16 115 mother–child dyads from lowland rural Nepal, we first determined the SRB in this population. We then identified individual markers of maternal capital, and also developed composite markers that captured the variability. Building on the conceptual model of embodied capital [45], traits that promote the capacity for maternal investment can be considered ‘maternal capital’ [46]. This term brings together diverse somatic, social and socio-economic components of maternal phenotype, which are all markers of the mother’s ability to invest in the offspring [46]. For example, mothers with more social capital may be able to bring together a wider pool of social support for childcare [47], mothers with greater education and empowerment may be able to steer more economic resources to childcare [48–50], and mothers with higher levels of lean and fat mass may be able to invest more through physiological pathways in foetal and infant growth respectively [51]. Using maternal capital markers as the exposure, we tested the overarching hypothesis that mothers with lower levels of capital were more likely to give birth to girls, compared to those with higher capital. We developed hypotheses for specific components of maternal capital as described in the methods section.

METHODOLOGY

Study profile

We analyse data from the cluster-randomized controlled Low Birth Weight South Asia Trial (LBWSAT) in rural lowland Nepal (Terai), which assessed the impact of interventions during pregnancy on the birth weight and growth of children from birth to 16 months of age [52]. The trial spanned 80 geographic clusters (Village Development Committees, VDCs) in southern Mahottari and Dhanusha districts bordering Bihar state in India. The Maithili-speaking Madhesi women of our study have the lowest median marriage age (15 years) and educational attainment (about three-fourths have no schooling) in Nepal [53, 54]. Families generally decide when and who girls marry and seclusion norms often restrict women to households, where they have low levels of agency [55, 56].

Of the 63 308 married women consenting to menstrual monitoring, 25 090 women aged 10–49 years fell pregnant and were recruited between December 2013 and February 2015 into one of three interventions: (i) Women’s Groups using the Participatory Learning and Action (PLA) behaviour change approach, (ii) PLA and unconditional cash transfers and (iii) PLA and food supplementation or (iv) a control group accessing Government of Nepal health services [52].

The Nepal Health Research Council (108/2012; 292/2018), University College London (4198/001, 0326/015) and University of Cambridge (1016, the secondary analysis only) granted research ethics approvals for the trial and secondary analysis of LBWSAT data. VDC secretaries consented to the inclusion of clusters. Written consent was obtained from women and guardians of married adolescents aged <18 years.

Data

Women’s age and their age at marriage were recorded in running years and converted to completed years (running years minus 1). Our outcome variable was sex of the child born into the LBWSAT, and our interest was in identifying the factors associated with having a ‘girl’. Exposures relating to maternal phenotype included:

  • Education: none, primary (1–5 years) or lower-secondary/higher (≥6 years);

  • Marriage age: ≤14 years, 15 years, 16–17 years or ≥18 years;

  • Parity: 0, 1, 2 or ≥3 births; and

  • Height: ≤144.9 cm, 145–154.9 cm or ≥155 cm.

Education was coded according to the Nepali education system [57]. In regression analyses, marriage was coded in two groups, below and above the median age of 15 years in our study population. Height was coded according to established cut-offs for this population for short stature [58], and our own cut-offs for taller stature.

Exposures relating to socio-economic characteristics included:

  • Caste: disadvantaged Muslim, disadvantaged Dalit, Middle (Janjati, Terai castes) or advantaged (Yadav, Brahmin);

  • Assets: quartiles, with 1 being the poorest and 4 the richest;

  • Land-holding: none, ≤0.5 hectares, 0.51–0.99 hectares or ≥1 hectare; and

  • Accessibility to bazaar: ≤30 , 31–89 or ≥90 minutes.

The asset score, land-holding and bazaar variables were coded according to the distribution in our data. Accessibility to the nearest big bazaar (with fixed stores) was measured in minutes using the usual form of transport.

The asset score was derived using principal component analysis (PCA). The first principal component had positive factor loadings for all 11 variables and was taken as the marker of material wealth. It accounted for 31.2% of the variability, compared to 10.9% and 9.7% from the second and third principal components. Variables contributing the highest factor loadings (weight) to the first principal component included: wall material (0.393), toilet type (0.382), roof material (0.382), flooring material (0.371), motorbike (0.311), number of rooms used for sleeping (0.302), television (0.272), access to electricity (0.237), drinking water source (0.209), non-biomass cooking fuel use (0.174) and computer (0.157). Land-holding was excluded from the asset score because we wanted to test its association with having a girl, independent of material wealth.

PCA, described below, was also used to derive two composite indices of maternal capital. The two components that emerged from this approach captured different axes of variability in maternal capital. One component is related to socio-economic resources, and the other to reproductive capital, as explained in more detail below. We then investigated their independent association with the odds of having a girl.

Hypotheses

We first use these data to test the following specific predictions:

  1. that mother’s lower stature, low education and early marriage age are independently associated with having a relatively high proportion of daughters;

  2. that independent of maternal phenotype, low paternal education, low household wealth and disadvantaged caste group are associated with having a relatively high proportion of daughters; and

  3. that easier accessibility to the nearest ‘big market’ (a proxy for access to technology for sex-specific abortions) is associated with a lower likelihood of having daughters.

We then explore two composite indices to get an overview of the independent associations of maternal socio-economic and reproductive capital components.

Statistical methods

We summarized women’s age and age at marriage with median and interquartile range given their skewed distributions. We used chi-squared tests (categorical variables) and non-parametric k-sample analysis of variance (Kruskal–Wallis test; continuous variables) to test (i) for differences in maternal and household traits by child’s sex, (ii) for bias in these characteristics where child sex was missing and (iii) for bias in child sex where key predictor variables were missing.

Data were scaled to unit variance before performing the PCA indexing socio-economic capital and maternal reproductive capital (confirmed by biplot, Supplementary Fig. S1). The first composite score derived from PCA explained 33.7% of variability. Variables contributing the highest factor loading (weight) included: maternal education (0.776), husband’s education (0.733), household assets (0.620), land-holding (0.481) and caste (0.462). As these individual variables all related to socio-economic traits, we refer to this composite marker as ‘socio-economic capital’. The second composite score explained 19.1% of variability. The variables contributing the highest factor loading (weight) were: maternal parity (0.740) and maternal age (0.719). Since later maternal age at childbirth and greater parity have both been associated with a greater birth weight of the offspring in this population [59], we refer to this composite marker as ‘reproductive capital’. Maternal height was not included in these indices because it would reduce our sample size, and, when included in the PCA on the dataset including available maternal height data it had a relatively low factor loading. In each case, the continuous composite scores were coded into quartiles, indicating low to high (1–4, respectively) levels of maternal socio-economic and reproductive capital.

A heatmap compared LBWSAT SRBs for the two composite indices relative to the global population SRB by adjusting for the UN-recognized average value, i.e. (105-LBWSAT SRB). We fitted mixed-effects logistic regression models with a random effect on the intercept accounting for within-cluster variability. We estimated adjusted odds ratios of having a girl with all of the maternal and household characteristics together, and by the two composite maternal capital indices. Models controlled for parity and maternal age. Goodness-of-fit was evaluated by the Nakagawa–Schielzeth conditional R2 value, which measures the percentage of variance explained by the model’s fixed and random effects [60]. The higher value of each trait was set as the reference group for exposure variables (e.g. richest households). For accessibility to big bazaar, the shortest time was set as the reference.

Models adjusted for trial arm, but as these associations were not statistically significant, they were not reported in tables. As the trial recruited pregnant married women, interventions could not have influenced women’s marriage age, education (which typically ends before/at marriage) or husband’s education and caste.

The SRB was calculated in Microsoft Excel (version 16.16.23). Statistical analyses were conducted in R version 4.04 [61] and RStudio version 1.4.1106 using the R libraries tidyverse [62] and lme4 [63] (mixed-effects regression models). The R library FactoMineR [64] was used to compute the two PCA composite ‘maternal capital’ indices and the PCA biplot.

RESULTS

Sample selection

Our main analysis comprised of 16 115 women. The analysis including maternal stature included a subset of 12 495 women with data on height. Of 25 090 married pregnant women recruited into the LBWSAT, we excluded 408 mothers with multiple pregnancies during the trial, 5731 mothers missing data on the outcome variable (sex of the infant born into the trial) and 2836 mothers missing data on exposures variables (Fig. 1).

Figure 1.

Figure 1.

Sample selection. The flowchart illustrates our sample selection. It shows which women were excluded, and the sample size used in the main analysis and subset of women with data on height

There were two factors that reduced the availability of data on offspring sex [65]. First, several thousand women (n = 5410) were recruited into the trial before the intervention began, or when the intervention was still being ‘run in’. These women delivered before birth data capture began. Second, the entire trial was brought to an end prematurely, and birth data capture was therefore halted before many women had delivered. Although many participants who missed birth data capture for these two reasons were subsequently captured through a ‘trial endpoint’ measurement, undertaken during infancy, the records show that 5731 recruited women never attended any follow-up after delivery, and hence the sex of the baby was not ascertained.

Compared to mothers with data on the sex of infant born into the trial, mothers with missing data on this variable showed trends to lower maternal age, greater education, lower parity, advantaged caste, greater household assets and large land (Supplementary Table S1). However, the magnitudes of these differences were trivial and therefore not expected to bias our results. There was no bias in child sex between the sample used in our analysis and those excluded for missing data on predictor variables (Supplementary Table S2).

Sample description

Of the 16 115 women in our sample, 52.8% (n = 8501) gave birth to a boy and 47.2% (n = 7614) to a girl. The SRB for the sample was thus 112. Compared to the global population SRB of 105, there were an additional 7 missing girls relative to 100 boys in our study. Simulations indicated that the SRB of the population with missing sex data (n = 5731) would need to be 84:100, in order to bring the SRB for the whole sample back to 105:100 (Supplementary Fig. S2).

Mothers’ median age was 21 years and 65% were uneducated compared to 49% of husbands (Table 1). Only 10% of women had married ≥18 years, with 35% ≤14 years, 26% at 15 years and 29% between 16 and 17 years. About 15% of women were of shorter stature, 65% of average height and 20% were tall. More than half of the mothers were of parity 0 or 1. About 35% of households were from the disadvantaged caste, 43% and 22% from the middle and advantaged castes respectively. Household assets were presented in quartiles. About 36% of the households owned no land, 32% ≤0.5 hectares, 47% between 0.51 and 0.99 hectares and 17% ≥1 hectare. Big bazaars were easily accessible to about half of the families, 41% lived 31–89 min away and 9% ≥90 min away.

Table 1.

Characteristics of sample and differences by sex of infant born into LBWSAT

Full sample
Boys
Girls
(n =16115)
(n =8501)
(n =7614)
Median IQR Median IQR Median IQR
Women’s age (years) 21 6 21 6 21 6
F % F % F % P-value a
Women’s education (years) 0.011
 None 10 455 64.9 5428 63.9 5027 66.0
 Primary (1–5 years) 1716 10.6 917 10.8 799 10.5
 Lower-secondary or higher (≥6 years) 3944 24.5 2156 25.4 1788 23.5
Women’s age at marriage (years) 0.486
 ≤14 years 5624 34.9 2926 34.4 2698 35.4
 15 years 4153 25.8 2224 26.2 1929 25.3
 16–17 years 4670 29.0 2476 29.1 2194 28.8
 ≥18 years 1668 10.4 875 10.3 793 10.4
Women’s height (cm) (n =12495) 0.038
 ≤144.9 cm 1926 15.4 979 14.8 947 16.2
 145–154.9 cm 8070 64.6 4287 64.6 3783 64.5
 ≥155 cm 2499 20.0 1367 20.6 1132 19.3
Parity (no. of births) 0.001
 0 5815 36.1 2999 35.3 2816 37.0
 1 4340 26.9 2261 26.6 2079 27.3
 2 3126 19.4 1653 19.4 1473 19.3
 ≥3 2834 17.6 1588 18.7 1246 16.4
Husband’s education (years) 0.036
 None 7949 49.3 4119 48.5 3830 50.3
 Primary (1–5 years) 1860 11.5 978 11.5 882 11.6
 Lower-secondary or higher (≥6 years) 6306 39.1 3404 40.0 2902 38.1
Caste affiliation 0.147
 Disadvantaged: Muslim 3140 19.5 1619 19.0 1521 20.0
 Disadvantaged: Dalit 2557 15.9 1323 15.6 1234 16.2
 Middle: Janjati, Terai castes 6887 42.7 3651 42.9 3236 42.5
 Advantaged: Yadav, Brahmin 3531 21.9 1908 22.4 1623 21.3
Household assets 0.006
 1: Poorest 4013 24.9 2040 24.0 1973 25.9
 2 4053 25.1 2116 24.9 1937 25.4
 3 4036 25.0 2153 25.3 1883 24.7
 4: Richest 4013 24.9 2192 25.8 1821 23.9
Land-holding 0.011
 None 5830 36.2 2980 35.1 2850 37.4
 ≤0.5 hectares 5230 32.5 2783 32.7 2447 32.1
 0.51–0.99 hectares 2343 14.5 1279 15.0 1064 14.0
 ≥1 hectare 2712 16.8 1459 17.2 1253 16.5
Accessibility to big bazaar 0.806
 ≤30 min 7996 49.6 4219 49.6 3777 49.6
 31–89 min 6605 41.0 3495 41.1 3110 40.8
 ≥90 min 1514 9.4 787 9.3 727 9.5

IQR, interquartile range; F, frequency.

P-values in bold indicate significance <0.05.

a

Chi-squared test.

Compared to boys, girls were more likely to come from lower capital mothers and households with lower parity and shorter mothers, uneducated parents, poorer and low land-holding households (Table 1). There were no differences by infant sex in maternal age, age at marriage or accessibility to bazaar.

The LBWSAT SRB by the two composite indices compared to global population SRB are shown in a heatmap (Fig. 2). In brackets, positive values indicated an excess of daughters and negative values indicated missing daughters relative to 100 sons. In each case, a lower quartile value indicated less capital, and these were the households and mothers to which girls were more likely to be born.

Figure 2.

Figure 2.

Heatmap of LBWSAT SRB by maternal capital composite indices 1 and 2 and excess girls or boys compared to global population SRB. The X axis is four groups of the first index and the Y axis is four groups of the second index. Each cell shows the SRB, Sex Ratio at Birth (males:females) in corresponding quartiles. In brackets, positive values = ‘excess daughters’ and negative values = ‘missing daughters’ relative to 100 sons. The number, n, in each cell is also shown. Differences in SRB between cells different by chi-squared test P < 0.001

Mixed-effects logistic regression models testing the association of each individual factor with the odds of having a girl are shown in Supplementary Table S3. The odds of having a girl were higher for primigravidae, early marrying and shorter mothers, and for uneducated parents, disadvantaged castes, poorer and landless households. Accessibility to bazaar was not associated with the odds of having a girl.

Multivariable mixed-effects logistic regression models showed that lower parity, uneducated and poor women had a greater likelihood of having a girl (Table 2, Model 1). Independent of these factors, shorter maternal stature, which may be a developmental marker, and marrying early were also associated with a greater likelihood of having a girl (Model 2).

Table 2.

Factors associated with the likelihood of having a girl

Model 1: Full sample
Model 2: Sub-sample with maternal height
n = 16 115 a
n = 12 495 b
Conditional R2 = 0.006
Conditional R2 = 0.007
aOR (95% CI) P-value aOR (95% CI) P-value
Women’s age (years) 1.00 (0.99, 1.01) 0.989 1.00 (0.99, 1.01) 0.911
Parity (no. of births)
 0 1.31 (1.14, 1.49) <0.001 1.30 (1.11, 1.51) 0.001
 1 1.25 (1.11, 1.40) <0.001 1.27 (1.11, 1.45) <0.001
 2 1.17 (1.05, 1.31) 0.005 1.18 (1.04, 1.33) 0.009
 ≥3 (ref) 1.00 1.00
Women’s education (years)
 None 1.10 (1.00, 1.21) 0.047 1.12 (1.00, 1.24) 0.043
 Primary (1–5 years) 1.04 (0.92, 1.17) 0.556 1.08 (0.95, 1.24) 0.240
 ≥Lower-secondary (≥6 years) (ref) 1.00 1.00
Women’s age at marriage (years)
 ≤14 years 1.07 (0.99, 1.14) 0.076 1.09 (1.01, 1.18) 0.036
 ≥15 years (ref) 1.00 1.00
Husband’s education (years)
 None 1.01 (0.93, 1.10) 0.801 0.98 (0.90, 1.08) 0.739
 Primary (1–5 years) 1.01 (0.90, 1.12) 0.896 1.00 (0.89, 1.14) 0.976
 ≥Lower-secondary (≥6 years) (ref) 1.00 1.00
Caste affiliation
 Disadvantaged: Muslim 1.04 (0.93, 1.16) 0.515 0.99 (0.87, 1.12) 0.824
 Disadvantaged: Dalit 1.05 (0.94, 1.18) 0.405 1.04 (0.91, 1.18) 0.575
 Middle: Janjati, Terai castes 1.03 (0.94, 1.12) 0.534 1.00 (0.91, 1.10) 0.980
 Advantaged: Yadav, Brahmin (ref) 1.00 1.00
Household assets
 1: Poorest 1.12 (1.00, 1.24) 0.041 1.17 (1.04, 1.32) 0.009
 2 1.07 (0.97, 1.18) 0.176 1.11 (0.99, 1.23) 0.073
 3 1.03 (0.94, 1.13) 0.467 1.07 (0.97, 1.19) 0.196
 4: Richest (ref) 1.00 1.00
Land-holding
 None 1.02 (0.91, 1.14) 0.784 0.99 (0.87, 1.12) 0.857
 ≤0.5 hectares 0.97 (0.88, 1.07) 0.564 0.95 (0.85, 1.06) 0.377
 0.51–0.99 hectares 0.95 (0.84, 1.06) 0.334 0.96 (0.84, 1.09) 0.492
 ≥1 hectare (ref) 1.00 1.00
Accessibility to big bazaar
 ≤30 min (ref) 1.00 1.00
 31–89 min 1.00 (0.93, 1.07) 0.897 1.00 (0.92, 1.08) 0.987
 ≥90 min 1.02 (0.90, 1.14) 0.777 1.08 (0.94, 1.23) 0.287
Maternal height (cm)
 ≤144.9 cm 1.15 (1.02, 1.29) 0.027
 145–154.9 cm 1.06 (0.97, 1.16) 0.214
 ≥155 cm (ref) 1.00
Intercept 0.62 (0.45, 0.85) 0.003 0.57 (0.39, 0.81) 0.002

aOR, adjusted odds ratio; 95% CI, 95% confidence interval.

P-values in bold indicate significance <0.05.

a

n =8501 boys versus n =7614 girls.

b

n =6633 boys versus n =5862 girls. Mixed-effects logistic regression models include fixed and random effects estimates for geographic clusters and control for trial arm. As associations of trial arm with the odds of having a girl were not statistically significant, they are not reported in the table.

The independent association of composite maternal index 1 (socio-economic capital) and composite maternal index 2 (reproductive capital) with the odds of having a girl are shown in Table 3. Mothers with the lowest level of socio-economic and reproductive capital had a greater likelihood of having a girl.

Table 3.

Association of two composite indices of the capacity for parental investment with the likelihood of having a girl

n =16 082 a
Conditional R2 = 0.005
aOR (95% CI) P-value
Composite index 1: socio-economic capitalb
 1: Low 1.29 (1.15, 1.44) <0.001
 2 1.19 (1.08, 1.30) <0.001
 3 1.12 (1.02, 1.24) 0.023
 4: High (ref) 1.00
Composite index 2: maternal reproductive capital
 1: Low 1.15 (1.04, 1.27) 0.006
 2 1.13 (1.02, 1.24) 0.018
 3 1.01 (0.91, 1.11) 0.885
 4: High (ref) 1.00
Intercept 0.71 (0.62, 0.81) <0.001

aOR, adjusted odds ratio; 95% CI, 95% confidence interval.

a

n = 8501 boys versus n =7614 girls.

b

Composite index 1: husband’s education, assets, maternal education, land and caste.

3 Composite index 2: maternal parity and age. Mixed-effects logistic regression models include fixed and random effects estimates for geographic clusters and control for trial arm. As associations of trial arm with the odds of having a girl were not statistically significant, they are not reported in the table.

P-values in bold indicate significance <0.05.

DISCUSSION

We investigated whether girls and boys have an equal chance of being born into households with a greater capacity to invest in their offspring. Our first key finding was that the SRB was 112:100. Relative to the United Nations (UN) value of 105:100 as the ‘expected SRB’ [2], this indicates a loss of 7 girls for every 100 boys. Although our study suffered from missing data, our calculations suggest that this is very unlikely to account for the observed SRB. High SRBs achieved through sex selection have been explained by Guilmoto through a ‘ready, willing and able’ framework [66], whereby families may be ready because they have a preference for sons, willing because of cultural acceptability of using prenatal sex selection of foetuses and able if they can access the appropriate technology for both foetal sex determination and abortion. This cultural manipulation of the SRB reflects a ‘fertility squeeze’ produced by declining fertility.

The overall SRB of 112 in our study was higher than values of 107 reported previously in Nepal, 110 in India and 109 in southern Asia [4]. However, this aggregate ratio masks substantial geographic variation across and within countries, and associations with parity. For example, a study of different communities in Bangladesh, Pakistan, India and Nepal estimated SRBs ranging from 102 to 128 [67]. The Nepal component of this study found that two adjoining hill districts in the western development region had SRBs of 114 and 102 [26]. Using 2016 DHS data, Channon et al. [5] estimated an overall SRB of 106, which was lower than our value, but also a conditional SRB of 115 for second births when the first-born was female. However, an estimation of DHS data from 2012–16 found an overall SRB of 111, which is closer to our study [29]. A high SRB of 112 was also found in a study of ∼9300 hospital births in Palpa District, southwest Nepal (2008–15) [68], while analysis of ∼75 000 births (2015–16) across six tertiary hospitals found an SRB of 117 [31].

Our second key finding, consistent with the first, is that girls were disproportionately born to mothers with reduced capacity to invest in them. This was evident both for individual markers of capital, such as lack of education, early marriage, shorter stature and poor households, and also for the two composite markers indexing maternal socio-economic and reproductive capital. We also found the highest SRB values in the families with the greatest socio-economic capital, suggesting that these families are likely to be actively aborting female foetuses, resulting in live births being strongly skewed towards boys. We found no indication that proximity to large bazaars predicted the likelihood of mothers having a girl, hence parental education and wealth are likely to have been the primary driving factors of such sex selection. It is also possible that the necessary technology is not available in all places with big shops.

Conversely, SRBs below 105 are likely to reflect both biological factors and the lack of access and means to pay for sex-diagnostic and abortion facilities. It is unlikely that the poorest families would be deliberately aiming to increase the likelihood of having daughters. First, they are least likely to have access to foetal sex detection and abortion facilities. Second, it is unlikely they would have an active preference for daughters, given the dowry costs associated with them, and the ‘missed opportunity’ to have a son who could contribute economically to the care of parents in old age. Therefore, we assume that the higher likelihood of daughters among families with lower reproductive and socio-economic capital, indicated by SRB values <105, indicates a contribution of biological mechanisms. This is particularly the case for the association of SRB with reproductive capital, where amongst families in the bottom quartile for socio-economic capital, there was a dose–response increasing the likelihood of having a girl. The one exception, where even poor families might seek to influence the sex of the child, is where family size is already high. This may explain the SRB of 118 in the lowest socio-economic quartile and the highest reproductive capital quartile. If poor families lack access to foetal sex detection and abortion facilities, then this may be achieved through infanticide, which was a commonly used method of birth control in some parts of Asia in the past [69]. However, evidence for infanticide in contemporary Nepal is inconsistent [70, 71].

Overall, our results indicate the differential use of sex-determining technology in association with family size, alongside girls being more likely to be born at lower parities and into larger, poorer and less educated families. Although we focused on the factors associated with a greater likelihood of female births, our findings are consistent with other studies investigating the factors associated with an elevated SRB or a greater likelihood of male births [33, 34]. For example, similar to our finding that poor uneducated mothers were more likely to bear daughters, other studies have found that boys are more likely to be born into richer and more educated families [5, 26, 28, 31, 67, 68]. Underlying factors linked with skewed SRB values in these studies likewise include persistent son preference, use of sex-determination technology and lower desired fertility [5, 17, 29, 66]. In Nepal, policy also matters, with the legalization of abortion (although not sex-determination technology) and a lack of community-based advocacy programmes promoting the value of girls associated with higher SRBs in some regions [26, 28, 67].

We have previously shown that maternal BMI rises with age and parity in this population, which might increase the likelihood of sons being born when mothers have higher reproductive capital [59]. A study in rural Ethiopia found similar results: compared to women in the lowest quartile of fat and muscle mass, those in the upper quartile were twice as likely to have a son [72]. Another possible contributing factor is greater male foetal mortality or stillbirths among families with lower socio-economic and reproductive capital, as modelled by the ‘frail male’ conceptual framework [15]. However, we did not have the data to address that issue. We also did not have any physiological data to explore what biological mechanisms may contribute to these associations, and hence our analysis cannot be considered a test of the Trivers–Willard hypothesis, which aimed to evaluate SRB variability in terms of its implications for maternal lifetime reproductive fitness [7]. Rather, our focus here was on the implications for daughters of being differentially born into families with a lower capacity to invest in them.

That girls are more likely to occupy a ‘lower capital niche’ in early life is of evolutionary importance because this exposure is associated with adverse adult health and human capital outcomes, and lower reproductive fitness [20–23]. We have previously shown in a Brazilian birth cohort that mothers with low physical and socio-economic capital have daughters that are themselves more likely to reproduce early, drop out of school, and be shorter in adult life [73]. Although low maternal capital may also impact sons, these effects would be reduced if on average in the population, sons were born to higher capital mothers compared to daughters.

Our findings have implications for understanding the inter-generational transmission of gender inequality [74]. The patterns we have demonstrated may contribute to the inter-generational propagation of gender inequality in this population, whereby less educated daughters marry at a younger age and into lower socio-economic status households, and then are more likely to give birth to daughters themselves who are exposed to the same developmental niche. A key issue is that even if parents do not express any gender bias, and would inherently invest equally in boys and girls after birth, the patterns we show here will still replicate gender inequality. For example, if both wealthy and poor families placed equal emphasis on taking girls and boys to a doctor, but if compared to boys, girls were relatively concentrated in poorer families who were less able to afford doctors, then overall in the population fewer girls than boys would be seen by doctors. Girls are also more likely to be born into larger families and at earlier parities, which can have consequences for their future prospects if families are either unwilling or unable to invest equally in each child [34]. These issues are likely to be important in Nepal, which ranks 110 out of 189 countries on the Gender Inequality Index, a composite measure reflecting inequality in achievement between women and men in reproductive health, empowerment and the labour market [75].

Strengths and limitations

Our study has some strengths, including the large sample size in a disadvantaged rural population, and the availability of data on a wide range of maternal and household characteristics.

The study also has several limitations. First, there were missing data on both offspring sex, and on maternal predictors. However, we think these are unlikely to bias our findings. Families with missing data on sex would have to have very strong bias to daughters to negate the observed overall SRB of 112. Similarly, differences between mothers with or lacking offspring sex in socio-economic variables were very modest, and again could only bias our findings if the associations of between these variables and sex were completely different from those observed in the main sample. There was also no difference in SRB between mothers included in the analysis versus excluded due to missing predictor data. Finally, the overall SRB is similar to that reported in other studies in Nepal. Overall, these patterns in combination with our simulations suggest that missing data are very unlikely to account for the patterns we observe.

Second, we have no direct information on foetal sex detection and abortion, and our interpretation of the data has to assume that these technologies and facilities are available and in demand in this population. This is similar to other studies in the region [5].

Third, given that we used all available socio-economic and reproductive traits in our PCA analysis, we could control only for confounders relating to the study design. There may be confounding factors that we did not measure that could contribute to the associations. Fourth, we cannot evaluate whether males had higher foetal mortality (and stillbirth) in lower socio-economic households, which could result in the higher concentration of female births. Fifth, we could not explore whether the sex of previous siblings increased the likelihood of having a girl, because not every participant answered this question.

Finally, our results apply to a relatively disadvantaged society with patrilineal patrilocal family structure, where son preference is strong and dowry payments for daughters present economic challenges. Our findings may not be generalizable outside the study context and similar populations.

CONCLUSIONS

Amartya Sen termed the global shortfall of women, from not only the expected number at birth but also throughout the life-course, as ‘missing women’ [76]. Arguably, not being given the chance to be born at all is the greatest form of discrimination against girls, and the SRB of 112 in our study suggests that this issue is evident in rural lowland Nepal. However, where son preference is high, some girls born are ‘unwanted’, and are likely to face a range of risks, which in some societies can include premature mortality arising from female infanticide and maltreatment and neglect during early childhood, adolescence and adulthood across a range of dimensions [24, 38, 39, 77]. We have added to this debate, by showing that in this population, on average girls are more likely than boys to be born into families with a lower capacity to invest in them.

Our results show that girls do indeed start life facing composite disadvantages compared to boys, being more likely than boys to be born to mothers with lower socio-economic status and lower reproductive capital. Such households are likely to have fewer resources to educate, feed and adequately care for all children. This may be compounded by the fact that in societies where sons are preferred, girls may not receive their fair share of support. This cycle of disadvantage and sex discrimination may then continue into the next generation.

SUPPLEMENTARY DATA

Supplementary data is available at EMPH online.

Supplementary Material

eoac029_Supplementary_Data

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

We are grateful to the women and their families for participating in the trial and the Public Health Offices of Dhanusha and Mahottari Districts in Nepal who supported the implementation of the trial. We thank staff from the Mother and Infant Research Activities (MIRA, Nepal) for data collection, and the UCL Institute for Global Health for their support (see Saville et al., 2018 for full details).

FUNDING

This research was supported by the Leverhulme Trust (RPG-2017-264) and National Institute for Health Research (NIHR) Great Ormond Street Hospital Biomedical Research Centre. The LBWSAT was funded by the Department for International Development (DFID) South Asian Research Hub (PO 5675). Funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.

Conflict of interest: None declared.

Contributor Information

Akanksha A Marphatia, Department of Geography, University of Cambridge, Cambridge CB2 3EN, UK; Population, Policy and Practice Research and Teaching Department, UCL Great Ormond Street Institute of Child Health, London WC1N 1EH, UK.

Naomi S Saville, Institute for Global Health, University College London, London WC1N 1EH, UK.

Dharma S Manandhar, Mother and Infant Research Activities, Kathmandu, Nepal.

Mario Cortina-Borja, Population, Policy and Practice Research and Teaching Department, UCL Great Ormond Street Institute of Child Health, London WC1N 1EH, UK.

Alice M Reid, Department of Geography, University of Cambridge, Cambridge CB2 3EN, UK.

Jonathan C K Wells, Population, Policy and Practice Research and Teaching Department, UCL Great Ormond Street Institute of Child Health, London WC1N 1EH, UK.

Data Availability

Requests to access the dataset, through a data sharing agreement, should be directed to Dr Naomi Saville, n.saville@ucl.ac.uk.

REFERENCES

  • 1. United Nations. World Population Prospects 2019, Online Edition. Rev. 1. 2019. 2019https://population.un.org/wpp/Download/Standard/Fertility/ (29 July 2021, date last accessed).
  • 2. UNFPA. Sex Imbalances at Birth: Current Trends, Consequences and Policy Implications. Bangkok, Thailand: UNFPA Asia and the Pacific Regional Office, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  • 3. Orzack SH, Stubblefield JW, Akmaev VR. et al. The human sex ratio from conception to birth. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 2015;112:E2102–11. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 4. Chao F, Gerland P, Cook AR. et al. Systematic assessment of the sex ratio at birth for all countries and estimation of national imbalances and regional reference levels. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 2019;116:9303–11. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 5. Channon MD, Puri M, Gietel-Basten S. et al. Prevalence and correlates of sex-selective abortions and missing girls in Nepal: evidence from the 2011 Population Census and 2016 Demographic and Health Survey. BMJ Open 2021;11:e042542. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6. West L, Grech V.. A systematic search of the factors that influence the sex ratio at birth. Early Hum Dev 2020;140:104865. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 7. Trivers R, Willard D.. Natural selection of parental ability to vary the sex ratio of offspring. Science 1973;179:90–2. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 8. Veller C, Haig D, Nowak MA.. The Trivers–Willard hypothesis: sex ratio or investment? Proc Biol Sci 2016;283:20160126. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 9. Cameron EZ. Facultative adjustment of mammalian sex ratios in support of the Trivers–Willard hypothesis: evidence for a mechanism. Proc Biol Sci 2004;271:1723–8. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 10. Cameron EZ, Dalerum F.. A Trivers-Willard effect in contemporary humans: male-biased sex ratios among billionaires. PLoS One 2009;4:e4195. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 11. Chacon-Puignau GC, Jaffe K.. Sex ratio at birth deviations in modern Venezuela: the Trivers-Willard effect. Soc Biol 1996;43:257–70. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 12. Wu H. Maternal stress and sex ratio at birth in Sweden over two and a half centuries: a retest of the Trivers-Willard hypothesis. Hum Reprod 2021;36:2782–92. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 13. Houdek P, Dvouletý O, Pažitka M.. Biological, environmental and socioeconomic determinants of the human birth sex ratio in the Czech Republic. J Biosoc Sci 2020;52:37–56. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 14. Kolk M, Schnettler S.. Socioeconomic status and sex ratios at birth in Sweden: no evidence for a Trivers-Willard effect for a wide range of status indicators. Am J Hum Biol 2016;28:67–73. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 15. Schacht R, Tharp D, Smith KR.. Sex ratios at birth vary with environmental harshness but not maternal condition. Sci Rep 2019;9:9066. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 16. Valente C. Civil conflict, gender-specific fetal loss, and selection: a new test of the Trivers–Willard hypothesis. J Health Econ 2015;39:31–50. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 17. Jayachandran S. Fertility decline and missing women. Am Econ J Appl Econ 2017;9:118–39. [Google Scholar]
  • 18. Madell DE, Hayward BP.. Gender inequities and global health outcomes. J Glob Health Rep 2019;3:e2019017. [Google Scholar]
  • 19. Morgan SP, Niraula BB.. Gender inequality and fertility in two Nepali villages. Popul Dev Rev 1995;21:541–61. [Google Scholar]
  • 20. Lummaa V. Early developmental conditions and reproductive success in humans: downstream effects of prenatal famine, birthweight, and timing of birth. Am J Hum Biol 2003;15:370–9. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 21. Victora C, Adair L, Fall C. et al. Maternal and child undernutrition: consequences for adult health and human capital. Lancet 2008;371:340–57. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 22. McMillen IC, MacLaughlin SM, Muhlhausler BS. et al. Developmental origins of adult health and disease: the role of periconceptional and foetal nutrition. Basic Clin Pharmacol Toxicol 2008;102:82–9. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 23. Behrman JR, Schott W, Mani S. et al. ; Young Lives Determinants and Consequences of Child Growth Project Team. Intergenerational transmission of poverty and inequality: parental resources and schooling attainment and children’s human capital in Ethiopia, India, Peru, and Vietnam. Econ Dev Cult Change 2017;65:657–97. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 24. Das Gupta M, Zhenghua J, Bohua L. et al. Why is son preference so persistent in East and South Asia? A cross-country study of China, India and the Republic of Korea. J Dev Stud 2003;40:153–87. [Google Scholar]
  • 25. Diamond-Smith N, Raj A, Prata N. et al. Associations of women’s position in the household and food insecurity with family planning use in Nepal. PLoS One 2017;12:e0176127. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 26. Puri M, Tamang A.. Understanding Factors Influencing Adverse Sex Ratios at Birth and Exploring What Works to Achieve Balance: The Situation in Selected Districts of Nepal. Kathmandu, Nepal: CREHPA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  • 27. Ebenstein A. Patrilocality and Missing Women. Jerusalem: Hebrew University of Jerusalem, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  • 28. Frost MD, Puri M, Hinde PRA.. Falling sex ratios and emerging evidence of sex-selective abortion in Nepal: evidence from nationally representative survey data. BMJ Open 2013;3:e002612. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 29. Tafuro S, Guilmoto CZ.. Skewed sex ratios at birth: a review of global trends. Early Hum Dev 2020;141:104868. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 30. Trivers RL. Social Evolution. Menlo Park, USA: Benjamin/Cummings, 1985. [Google Scholar]
  • 31. Pradhan E, Pearson E, Puri M. et al. Determinants of imbalanced sex ratio at birth in Nepal: evidence from secondary analysis of a large hospital-based study and nationally-representative survey data. BMJ Open 2019;9:e023021. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 32. Gellatly C, Petrie M.. Prenatal sex selection and female infant mortality are more common in India after firstborn and second-born daughters. J Epidemiol Community Health 2017;71:269–74. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 33. Clark S. Son preference and sex composition of children: evidence from India. Demography 2000;37:95–108. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 34. Basu D, De Jong R.. Son targeting fertility behavior: some consequences and determinants. Demography 2010;47:521–36. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 35. Keller MC, Nesse RM, Hofferth S.. The Trivers–Willard hypothesis of parental investment: no effect in the contemporary United States. Evol Hum Behav 2001;22:343–60. [Google Scholar]
  • 36. Beltrán Tapia FJ, Raftakis M.. Sex ratios and gender discrimination in Modern Greece. Popul Stud 2022;76:329–18. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 37. Marco‐Gracia FJ, Beltrán Tapia FJ.. Son preference, gender discrimination, and missing girls in rural Spain, 1750–1950. Popul Dev Rev 2021;47:665–89. [Google Scholar]
  • 38. Guilmoto CZ, Saikia N, Tamrakar V. et al. Excess under-5 female mortality across India: a spatial analysis using 2011 census data. Lancet Glob Health 2018;6:e650–8. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 39. Kaul T. Intra-household allocation of educational expenses: gender discrimination and investing in the future. World Dev 2018;104:336–43. [Google Scholar]
  • 40. UIS. Nepal Education Data. Nepal Country Snapshot. 2022. http://uis.unesco.org/country/np (27 April 2022, date last accessed).
  • 41. Aryal K. A Steep Climb Uphill: does geography and environment create barriers to secondary-aged girls’ equitable access to, and participation in education in remote areas of Nepal? Unpublished MSc Thesis. London South Bank University, 2014.
  • 42. Harris-Fry HA, Paudel P, Shrestha N. et al. Status and determinants of intra-household food allocation in rural Nepal. Eur J Clin Nutr 2018;72:1524–36. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 43. Chorghade G, Barker M, Kanade S. et al. Why are rural Indian women so thin? Findings from a village in Maharashtra. Public Health Nutr 2006;9:9–18. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 44. Raj A, McDougal LP, Silverman JG.. Gendered effects of siblings on child malnutrition in South Asia: cross-sectional analysis of demographic and health surveys from Bangladesh, India, and Nepal. Matern Child Health J 2015;19:217–26. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 45. Kaplan H, Lancaster J, Robson A.. Embodied capital and the evolutionary economics of the human life span. Popul Dev Rev 2003;29:152–82. [Google Scholar]
  • 46. Wells J. Maternal capital and the metabolic ghetto: an evolutionary perspective on the transgenerational basis of health inequalities. Am J Hum Biol 2010;22:1–17. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 47. Blaffer Hrdy S. Mothers and Others: The Evolutionary Origins of Mutual Understanding. Cambridge, USA: Harvard University Press, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  • 48. Smith L, Ramakrishnan U, Ndiaye A. et al. The Importance of Women’s Status for Child Nutrition in Developing Countries. Washington DC, USA: IFPRI, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  • 49. Shroff M, Griffiths P, Suchindran C. et al. Does maternal autonomy influence feeding practices and infant growth in rural India? Soc Sci Med 2011;73:447–55. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 50. Adhikari R, Sawangdee Y.. Influence of women’s autonomy on infant mortality in Nepal. Reprod Health 2011;8:7–8. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 51. Wells JC. Life history trade-offs and the partitioning of maternal investment: implications for health of mothers and offspring. Evol Med Public Health 2018;2018:153–66. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 52. Saville NM, Shrestha BP, Style S. et al. Impact on birth weight and child growth of Participatory Learning and Action women’s groups with and without transfers of food or cash during pregnancy: findings of the low birth weight South Asia cluster-randomised controlled trial (LBWSAT) in Nepal. PLoS One 2018;13:e0194064. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 53. MOHP, New ERA, ICF International. Nepal Demographic and Health Survey 2016. Kathmandu, Nepal: Ministry of Health and Population Nepal, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  • 54. Marphatia A, Saville N, Amable G. et al. How much education is needed to delay women’s age at marriage and first pregnancy in lowland Nepal? Front Public Health 2019;7:396–17. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 55. Maharjan S, Sah RK.. Madheshi women in Nepal. In: Tewari R, Sah AP (eds.). The Landscape of Madhesh: Politics, Society and Economy of the Plains. Kopundole, Lalitpur, Nepal: Nepal Madhesh Foundation, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  • 56. Gram L, Morrison J, Sharma N. et al. Validating an agency-based tool for measuring women’s empowerment in a complex public health trial in rural Nepal. J Human Dev Capabil 2017;18:107–35. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 57. Ministry of Education Nepal. School Sector Development Plan, Nepal, 2016/17–2022/23. Kathmandu, Nepal: Government of Nepal, Ministry of Education, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  • 58. Özaltin E, Hill K, Subramanian S.. Association of maternal stature with offspring mortality, underweight, and stunting in low- to middle-income countries. JAMA 2010;303:1507–16. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 59. Wells JCK, Marphatia AA, Cortina-Borja M. et al. Maternal physical, socioeconomic, and demographic characteristics and childbirth complications in rural lowland Nepal: applying an evolutionary framework to understand the role of phenotypic plasticity. Am J Hum Biol 2021;33:e23566. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 60. Nakagawa S, Schielzeth H.. A general and simple method for obtaining R2 from generalized linear mixed-effects models. Methods Ecol Evol 2013;4:133–42. [Google Scholar]
  • 61. R Core Team. R: A Language and Environment for Statistical Computing. Vienna, Austria: The R Foundation for Statistical Computing, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  • 62. Wickham H, Averick M, Bryan J. et al. Welcome to the Tidyverse. J Open Source Softw 2019;4:1686. [Google Scholar]
  • 63. Bates D, Mächler M, Bolker B. et al. Fitting linear mixed-effects models using lme4. J Stat Softw 2014;67:1–48. [Google Scholar]
  • 64. Lê S, Josse J, Husson F.. FactoMineR: an R package for multivariate analysis. J Stat Softw 2008;25:1–18. [Google Scholar]
  • 65. Saville NM, Manandhar DS, Wells JC.. Trial Experience and Data Capture in the Low Birth Weight South Asia Trial, a Large Cluster-Randomised Controlled Trial in Lowland Nepal. London, UK: UCL Discovery, 2020. https://discovery.ucl.ac.uk/id/eprint/10120616/ (20 April 2021, date last accessed). [Google Scholar]
  • 66. Guilmoto CZ. The sex ratio transition in Asia. Popul Dev Rev 2009;35:519–49. [Google Scholar]
  • 67. Population Council, CREHPA. Gender-Biased Sex Selection and Unbalanced Sex Ratios at Birth in South Asia: Case Studies of the Situation and Promising Approaches to Restore Balance. New Delhi, India: Population Council, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  • 68. Aryal S, Kalakheti B.. Sex ratio at birth in a tertiary care hospital in Western Nepal are the Trends Changing? J Nepal Paediatr Soc 2016;36:68–71. [Google Scholar]
  • 69. Drixler FF, Kok J.. A lost family-planning regime in eighteenth-century Ceylon. Popul Stud 2016;70:93–114. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 70. CREHPA. Sex Selection: Pervasiveness and Preparedness in Nepal. Kathmandu, Nepal: CREHPA, UNFPA, APCRSH, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  • 71. Vickery M, van Teijlingen ER.. Female infanticide in India and its relevance to Nepal. J Manmohan Mem Inst Health Sci 2018;3:79–85. [Google Scholar]
  • 72. Gibson MA, Mace R.. Strong mothers bear more sons in rural Ethiopia. Proc Biol Sci 2003;270:S108–9. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 73. Wells JCK, Cole TJ, Cortina-Borja M. et al. Low maternal capital predicts life history trade-offs in daughters: why adverse outcomes cluster in individuals. Front Public Health 2019;7:1–20. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 74. Osmani S, Sen A.. The hidden penalties of gender inequality: fetal origins of ill-health. Econ Hum Biol 2003;1:105–21. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 75. UNDP. Human Development Report 2020. The Next Frontier. Human Development and the Anthropocene. New York, NY: UNDP, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  • 76. Amartya S. Missing women—revisited. BMJ 2003;327:1297–8. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 77. Shaankar A. Gender and son meta-preference: is development itself an antidote. Econ Surv 2017;1:102–18. [Google Scholar]

Associated Data

This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

Supplementary Materials

eoac029_Supplementary_Data

Data Availability Statement

Requests to access the dataset, through a data sharing agreement, should be directed to Dr Naomi Saville, n.saville@ucl.ac.uk.


Articles from Evolution, Medicine, and Public Health are provided here courtesy of Oxford University Press

RESOURCES