Abstract
Background
In medicine, a wide gap exists between the medical care that ought to be possible in the light of the current state of medical research and the care that is actually provided. Behavioral biases and noise are two major reasons for this.
Methods
We present the findings of a selective literature review and illustrate how interventions based on behavioral economics can help physicians make better decisions and thereby improve treatment outcomes.
Results
A number of behavioral economics interventions, making use of, for example, default settings, active decision rules, social norms, and self-commitments, may improve physicians’ clinical decision-making. Evidence on long-term effects is, however, mostly lacking.
Conclusion
Despite their apparent potential, the application of behavioral economic interventions to improve medical decision-making is still in its infancy, particularly in Germany.
In medicine, there exists a gap between what ought to be possible and what is actually achieved in care provision. One important reason for this gap is bounded rational behavior which then goes on to exacerbate many health problems such as hypertension, diabetes, and obesity. It is estimated that up to 40% of premature deaths in industrialized countries are attributed to largely preventable behaviors (1). Recommendations from doctors are not followed, alcohol and nicotine are consumed excessively, people have unhealthy diets and too little exercise (1– 3). Currently, a frequently asked question is whether enough people are seeking vaccination against COVID-19 (4, 5).
cme plus
This article has been certified by the North Rhine Academy for Continuing Medical Education. Participation in the CME certification program is possible only over the internet: cme.aerzteblatt.de. The deadline for submission is 22 September 2023.
New treatment methods alone will not bring about a reduction in morbidity and mortality. People can be helped to make and implement decisions that are consistent with their own demands and goals (1, e1). It is often assumed that providing adequate understanding alone could produce good decisions. But this idea rests on an optimistic self-image of the human being, namely the image of a (fully) rational decision-maker who pursues clearly defined goals, rationally processes all available information, and makes decisions under perfect self-control. This self-image is misleading (e2). We know, for example, that smoking, little exercise, poor medication compliance, and using a cellphone while driving can cause us harm, yet we sometimes fail to act accordingly.
Even well-informed doctors are not always immune to such behavioral flaws: A recent empirical study from the United States shows that physicians often do not behave significantly differently when it comes to health than the general population with similar levels of education (6). Guideline-adherence to medication use can also be significantly lower among physicians than among people without medical expertise (7). The reason is our habits as well as our choice architecture (that is, the linguistic, physical, emotional, and social environment in which people make decisions) which make it harder for us to reach good decisions. Along with this, we have systematic biases in information processing and decision-making. This is the point of departure of behavioral economics research.
The image of the rational decision-maker has dominated economics for decades and is the basis of many public health measures (for example, tobacco taxes). In recent years, however, behavioral economics approaches have been increasingly used in health policy to foster healthy lifestylse, for example, with regard to nutrition, to reduce excessive cigarette and alcohol consumption, and to increase vaccination rates (3, e3– e5). So far, these measures have addressed primarily insured persons and patients, but not physicians (8, 9). The relevance of behavioral economics approaches is highlighted by the creation of behavioral insights teams, or nudge units, in the UK and many other countries, in international organizations (for example, World Health Organization), in health insurance companies, and in digital companies involved in the science and practice of behavior change. Nudge units are assigned to important decision-maker entities (for example, the British Cabinet Office, which supports government work).
Yet, when it comes to improving clinical decision-making of physicians, the application of the behavioral economics approach is still in its infancy (10). Every day, physicians make numerous, sometimes complex, decisions about patients’ diagnoses and treatment plans, sometimes with only limited information and under time pressure (11, 12). By necessity, the decision-making process is also guided by heuristics. These are abbreviated cognitive operations to allow quick, workable decisions despite incomplete information (e2). Heuristics are susceptible to cognitive biases that also have an impact on decisions by physicians regarding patient treatment and care (13). Behavioral economic approaches can help shape information flows for physicians and decision-making processes by physicians to improve patient care (14, e6, e7).
bounded rational behavior
Behavioral economics combines concepts from economics, psychology, and computer sciences to unravel decision-making processes and human behavior and explain deviations from a fully rational decision (15, 16). Based on this, decision-making architectures can be created to help reach good decisions (17, 18).
For example, people tend to behave inconsistently when it comes to time, often attaching disproportionately more importance to the present (present bias) and postponing unpleasant tasks till later (procrastination) (19, 20). An experiment by Read and van Leeuwen shows that 74% of participants ordered healthy food for a meeting planned for the future. On the other hand, the majority of test subjects (70%) preferred to order chocolate for a meeting currently in progress (e8). We are always a “better” person tomorrow—but the problem is: We are not living in the future, but in the here and now.
Individuals are more motivated by avoiding losses than by acquiring equivalent gains (loss aversion), and they overestimate the probability of positive events (optimism bias), while underestimating the probability of negative events (for example, the negative impact of their behavior on their health) (21, 22). Availability heuristic describes how people misperceive the likelihood of an event depending on how easily the idea comes to their mind (23). For example, doctors who have already encountered bacteremia in one patient will also make the same diagnosis more often in the future (24). Status quo bias results in preferring to maintain the current state of affairs so that alternative options are rejected excessively often (25). This list could go on and on. The question is: Is there a remedy for this?
This article provides examples of behavioral economics interventions aimed at improving doctors’ clinical decision-making. The focus is not on treatment and prevention strategies from the patient’s perspective nor on health policy interventions. The reported interventions were compiled using a selective literature review in PubMed (English search terms: “behavioral economics+intervention+physician”, published after 2013) and from studies known to us.
The impact of behavioral economics interventions on physicians’ decision-making
Default setting and active decision control
Decisions are influenced by context, and it is often possible to actively create this context, or choice architecture (e9). Thus, default settings can remain in place until they are actively changed. They are chosen in different ways and so influence behavior. Examples include settings for computer programs, cell phones and data protection laws, regulations covering objection to organ donation, and the automatic enrolment in private retirement schemes, e.g., the US 401(k)-plan (e10– e12). Typically, a distinction is made between a default setting to regulate consent (opt-in) or objection (opt-out). Active choice directly prompts the decision-maker to make a choice without a pre-selected option (e10, e13).
Initial research in a clinical context reveals that changes to their decision-making architecture influence the behavior of physicians (e14). Changing the default setting reduced the excessive prescription of originator drugs instead of generic equivalents. In a quasi-experimental study involving internists and general practitioners, the electronic decision support system linked to electronic health records changed the default setting for physicians from “originator and generic” to “generic”, with the option to change the default setting. This increased prescriptions of equivalent generic beta-blockers, statins, and proton pump inhibitors by an aggregate of 5.4 percentage points as compared with the preintervention period (95% confidence interval: [2.2; 8.7], p <0.001) (26, 27) (Table 1a– Table 1c).
Table 1a. Behavioral economic interventions directed at physician decision-making behavior – Example: Default setting and active choice.
Approach | Intervention | Design and method | Main outcomes |
Patel et al., 2014 (26); USA; Clinic of the University of Pennsylvania Health System; Community Health Data Base | |||
default, opt-out | Default setting on the electronic health record is preset to “generics“ for medication prescriptions with the option to disagree (opt-out) | Quasi-experimental study; 9 months; internists and general practitioners (N = 255); comparison: prescription of equivalent generic beta-blockers, statins, and proton pump inhibitors before and after the intervention | Prescription of equivalent generic beta-blockers, statins, and proton pump inhibitors before the intervention: internists 77.3%, general practitioners: 82.7%; after the intervention: internists: 83.1%, general practitioners: 83.0% (p <0.001) |
Patel et al., 2016 (27); USA; Outpatient departments of the University of Pennsylvania Health System; Community Health Data Base | |||
default, opt-out | Default setting for medication prescription set to “generics”, option to change this by setting an additional checkmark | Field experiment, difference-in-differences method, 17 months; physicians; all outpatient clinics of the University of Pennsylvania Health System; comparison: prescription of generics for 10 oral drugs before and after the intervention | Prescription of generics for 10 oral drugs before the intervention: 75.3%; after intervention: 98.4% (p <0.001) |
Patel et al., 2016 (28); USA; Hospital of the University of Pennsylvania Health System | |||
active choice | Intervention group: Decision whether colonoscopy or mammography should be requested for a patient or not by accepting or rejecting such a default suggestion or not Control group: no active choice intervention decision without default setting | Field experiment, difference-in-differences method; 2 years; physicians from 1 intervention and 2 control internal medicine clinics of the University of Pennsylvania Health System; comparison: number of requests and utilization of colonoscopy or mammography in the intervention group compared with the control group | Colonoscopy, request before intervention: intervention group: 42.4%, control group: 23.4%; after intervention: intervention group: 49.0%, control group: 19.5% Colonoscopy utilization before intervention: intervention group: 16.5%, control group: 10.7%; after intervention: intervention group: 17.1%, control group: 8.0% Mammography, request before intervention: intervention group: 50.5%, control group: 37.7%; after intervention: intervention group: 64.0%, control group: 36.9% Mammography utilization before intervention: intervention group: 38.5%, control group: 26.6%; after intervention: intervention group: 41.2%, control group: 29.5% Intervention group compared with control group: request: colonoscopy: +11.8% (95% confidence interval: [8.0; 15.6], p <0.001), mammography: +12.4% [8.7; 16.2], p <0.001; utilization: colonoscopy: +3.5% ([1.1; 5.9, p = 0.004), mammography: +2.2 %, [–1.0; –5.5], p = 0.18 |
Table 1c. Behavioral economic interventions applying to physician decision-making behavior – Example: Self-commitment.
Approach | Intervention | Design and method | Main outcomes |
Meeker et al., 2014 (35); USA; Primary care | |||
public commitment | Intervention group: Signed commitment by physicians to reduce inappropriate antibiotic prescription which was displayed in the examination rooms in poster size for patients to see |
Randomized controlled study; 9 months baseline, 12 weeks intervention; primary care practitioners (N = 14) Comparison: reduction in inappropriate antibiotic prescribing by an intervention compared with baseline and control group |
Antibiotic prescriptions Baseline: intervention group: 43.5 %, control group: 42.8%; intervention period: intervention group: 33.7 %, control group: 52.7% intervention group compared with baseline: –9.8% [0.0; –19.3] control group compared with baseline: 9.9 % [0.0; 20.2] intervention group compared with control group: –19.7% ([–5.8; –33.04], p = 0.02) |
Sacarny et al., 2018 (36); USA, Primary care; Choosing Wisely campaign | |||
self-commitment, reminder | All: 2-month control period, signed commitment to adhere to recommendations for ordering services of low medical value; use of post-it reminders of their commitment during the intervention period (1–6 months); follow-up period of 3 months | Stepped-wedge cluster randomized controlled trial; 12 months; primary care physicians (N = 45) Comparison: requests for low-value services during and after the intervention compared with before the intervention |
Unnecessary medical treatment requests during the intervention period compared with the control period: low-back pain: –1.2 % [–2.0; –0.5]), p = 0.001; headache: 0.7 % [–0.7; –2.1], p = 0.34; acute sinusitis: –1.4 % [–2.9; –0.1], p = 0.06 Follow-up period compared with control period: low back pain: –0.3% [–1.3; –0.8], p = 0.62; headache: 0.3% [–0.6; –1.2], p = 0.52; acute sinusitis: –2.7% [–6.6; –1.3], p = 0.19 |
Using mandatory active choice can help improve medical decisions, especially when it comes to the utilization of screening programs. In a randomized controlled trial, physicians were asked to sign into the patient’s electronic health record and decide whether they should be recommended for colonoscopy or mammography. The use of active choice resulted in a significant 12 percentage point increase in the number of requests for these screening tests as compared with a control group with no prompt to decide (colonoscopy: 11.8%, [8.0; 15.6], p <0.001; mammography: 12.4%, [8.7; 16.2], p <0.001). A significant increase in utilization by patients was observed only for colonoscopies (3.5%, [1.1; 5.9], p = 0.004) (28). Similar effects were seen following the introduction of active decision rules for influenza vaccinations, guideline-compliant prescriptions for statins, blood donations, HIV screening, and medication deliveries (e15– e18).
Social norms
An important finding from behavioral economics research is that people evaluate outcomes as gains or losses and express preferences relative to an existing reference point (21). One’s own performance and results are compared with those of others in a group (peer comparison) or with existing social norms (social norm comparison) (e19, e20). Social norms can be understood as standards of behavior within a group signalizing a desirable behavior and on which members of the group can orientate themselves (e21). Behavioral economic interventions incorporate this (29).
Social norms can play an important role in communication with physicians—for example, when they are informed about their own particular position with regard to their prescribing habits relative to physicians from comparable specialties and regions or to a norm that is desirable from a medical perspective (for example, a guideline). In a randomized controlled trial, a letter intervention containing a group comparison (“extremely high antipsychotic prescribing compared to other Maryland physicians”) reduced excess antipsychotic prescribing by approximately 11% of treatment days per prescriber as compared with the prescribing habits of a control group not sent peer comparison letters ([-13.1; -9.2], p <0.001) (30).
Other peer comparisons involve adjustments to prescriptions of antibiotics. In a randomized controlled trial using electronic health records, primary care practitioners were informed by email about their own inappropriate antibiotic prescriptions compared with the top performers (10% of physicians with the fewest inappropriate antibiotic prescriptions). The intervention was able to reduce inappropriate antibiotic prescriptions by 5.2% compared with prescribing habits in a control group ([-6.9; -1.6], p <0.001; and a reduction from 19.9% to 3.7% for peer comparison) (31). Similar effects were found regarding antibiotic prescribing for acute respiratory infections (odds ratio 0.73 [0.53; 0.995], p <0.05) (e21).
A randomized controlled trial in the United Kingdom applied the principle of avoiding “unnecessary antibiotic prescriptions” in an intervention in which the Chief Medical Officer, the UK government’s principal advisor on health issues, sent letters to general practitioners whose antibiotic prescription rate was more than 80% higher than those of all physicians in their local districts. This resulted in a 3.3% decrease in antibiotic prescriptions as compared with the prescribing habits of a control group that did not receive the letter (incidence rate ratio [IRR] 0.967 [0.957; 0.977], p <0.001) (32). A controlled field experiment in Germany showed that expert feedback on treatment duration (reference point) reduced the amount of antibiotics administered by pediatricians for routine cases by 10% (p <0.001) (33).
Self-commitment
Many people intend to eat more healthily, take their medication more regularly, or stop smoking. As the future draws nearer, these intentions sometimes fail to materialize. The reasons for this are time-inconsistent preferences (present bias) and lack of self-control. Binding commitments can help to achieve one’s own goals. Commitment devices employ, for example, loss aversion or safeguarding against being disappointed by others to counteract self-control problems. One of these devices is deposit contracts, whereby people voluntarily deposit money which they can only access again if they achieve a set goal (34). These self-commitments can help people eat more healthily, do more exercise, and stop smoking (e23). Commitments have two features: On the one hand, people willingly enter into commitments (that is, they are aware of possible discrepancies between goals and future behavior), while having to face consequences if goals are not achieved on the other hand. Commitments can close the intention-behavior gap.
There are also studies in the clinical setting on the effect of self-commitment by physicians (e24– e26). A randomized controlled trial examined the effect of public commitment on antibiotic prescriptions. In primary care clinics in the USA, physicians signed letters committing them to a rational prescription of antibiotics which were then displayed as posters in examination rooms for patients to see. This intervention resulted in a significant reduction of inappropriate prescriptions for antibiotics in comparison with prescription habits of the control group (-19.7% [-5.8; -33.04], p = 0.02) (35). It should be noted that when analyzing the effects of behavioral economics interventions, large-scale randomized field studies of antibiotic prescribing cannot usually determine whether individual patients who should have been prescribed an antibiotic in fact failed to receive it. Although such behavior cannot be ruled out, Eilermann et al., in whose study the decisions of the physicians participating in the experiment can be traced for each patient case, show that the reduction in antibiotic administration cannot be attributed to such behavior (33).
Another randomized trial involving primary care clinics in the USA examined precommitments to avoid services of low medical value as part of the Choosing Wisely campaign involving imaging for uncomplicated low back pain, imaging for uncomplicated headache, and unnecessary antibiotics for acute sinusitis. The precommitments were further reinforced by regular reminders. The intervention resulted in a small, but statistically significant, effect on imaging reduction for low back pain (-1.2% [-2.0; -0.5], p = 0.001). However, the effect was no longer evident three months after the intervention (-0.3% [-1.3; 0.8], p = 0.620). There was no significant change in the other low-value services (36). In 2013, the German Society of Internal Medicine also introduced a similar “smart decision-making” initiative in Germany to identify promising evidence-based diagnostic and therapeutic interventions (37). The question of whether the resulting recommendations are effectively applied in patient care cannot yet be conclusively answered (e27). Here, too, behavioral economic findings and experimental studies can utilized as additions to optimize decision-making processes.
Outlook
Behavioral economics can help close the wide gap between what ought to be medically possible and what is actually provided by offering treatment for behavioral errors and biases. People fail their own goals and process information in an inadequate and biased manner—but they do not simply behave irrationally or chaotically. Human behavior satisfies its own systematic and predictable rules. This creates opportunities for interventions to present information and shape decision architecture which can help physicians and patients make better decisions. A recent and important example involves the contributions of behavioral economics towards public health measures to increase COVID-19 vaccination rates (e28– e30).
Prevailing inconsistences of medical judgement are not only driven by biases but also by noise, the unsystematic variability within decision-making (38). Different experts may evaluate the same facts very differently. The creation of effective decision hygiene is recommended to reduce the effects of noise (38). Multidisciplinary tumor boards have been shown to be helpful in evaluating surgical interventions in cancer patients, often leading to revision of initial treatment decisions (38, e31). In addition, approaches already successful in quality circles (e32, e33) could be further enhanced by behavioral economics approaches.
Ethical standards must not be ignored in all these types of interventions. Consideration must be given to possible objections to behavioral interventions, including any constraints on core moral values—such as freedom, autonomy, and respect. Whatever the case, behavioral interventions should be made transparent, goals must be clearly defined, and the freedom of action of the target groups should not generally be restricted (e34, 39, 40). This is especially true as technological advances and greater data availability continually increase the effectiveness of behavior change interventions (e35). At the same time, however, it would be negligent in many cases to fail to review and continuously evaluate choice architectures to determine whether they create disincentives or encourage misconduct (e34). Finally, it is vital to consider long-term effects, as well as possibly different effects, of behavioral economic measures on different groups of people, something which is hardly to be found in the literature to date (e36, e37).
Behavioral economics, in combination with experimental methodology, provides both a conceptual framework and a practical toolbox. Theory-driven randomized laboratory and field experiments provide useful insights into the causal mechanisms of interventions (33, e38– e41). Insights into biases and preferences also contribute to the development of patient-centered prevention and treatment strategies.
With the increasing use of algorithms and artificial intelligence, behavioral science findings on the interdependence of information design processes and decision environments in clinical decision-making are becoming more important and digital interventions more effective (10, e35). Multidisciplinary collaboration between medical experts, behavioral economist, and data/computer scientists is already quite common practice in several corporations and organizations, with the recent collaboration in a clinical context (for example, Penn Medicine Nudge Unit) (e42). In addition, there already exists a great, and so far, largely untapped, potential to jointly develop innovative “therapeutic measures” against irrational behavior for the benefit of patients.
Table 1b. Behavioral economic interventions directed at physician decision-making behavior—Example: Social norms.
Approach | Intervention | Design and method | Main outcomes |
Sacarny et al., 2018 (30); USA; Federal State of Maryland; Primary care | |||
peer comparison, social norms | Intervention group: information letter about antipsychotics prescription rate of own practice in comparison with other practices (peer comparison). Control group: placebo letter discussing a different, unrelated medical topic |
Randomized controlled study; 2 years; general practitioners and internists (N = 5055); comparison: prescribing of antipsychotics between intervention and control group | Days of antipsychotic treatment after intervention: intervention group: 2456 days, control group: 2864 days of antipsychotic treatment of the intervention group compared with the control group after intervention: –11.1% (95% confidence interval [–13.1; –9.2], p <0.001) |
Meeker et al., 2016 (31); USA; Boston and Los Angeles; Primary care | |||
peer comparison, social norms | Peer comparison: monthly feedback on practice’s antibiotic prescribing rate compared with other practices Control group: no intervention | Cluster randomized controlled study; 18 months; primary care physicians (N =248) Comparison: inappropriate antibiotic prescribing in the intervention groups compared with the control group | Inappropriate antibiotic prescriptions before versus after intervention (peer comparison): control group: 24.1% versus 13.1%: 19.9% versus 3.7 % (p <0.001); comparison with the control group: –5.2% ([–6.9; –1.6], p <0.001) |
Hallsworth et al., 2016 (32); United Kingdom; Primary care | |||
social norms, feedback | Intervention group: information letter addressed to physician or patient with feedback on high antibiotic prescribing rate in the practice Control group: no feedback |
Randomized controlled study (2 x 2 factorial design); 8 months; general practitioner practices (N = 1581) Comparison: antibiotic prescribing in the intervention and control group | Antibiotic prescribing after intervention in intervention group compared with the control group: –3.3% (IRR 0.967 [0.957; 0.977], p <0.0001) |
Eilermann et al., 2019 (33); Germany; Pediatric care | |||
social norms, feedback | Intervention group: Antibiotic prescribing in hypothetical cases in three stages 1 st Stage: no feedback 2 nd Stage: expert feedback announced beforehand, then provided 3 rd Stage: see stage 2 Control group: no feedback |
Controlled field experiment (framed field experiment); pediatricians (N = 73) Comparison: antibiotic prescribing (for hypothetical patients) before and after expert feedback compared with control group before and after the intervention |
Average recommended length of antibiotic therapy in the intervention group: Stage 1: 7.98 days [7.42; 8.53]; Stage 2: 7.83 days [7.31; 8.35]; Stage 3: 7.23 days [6.93; 7.53]; change in recommended length of antibiotic therapy in Stage 2 compared with Stage 1: intervention group (−0.15; SD 0.63 [–0.34; –0.06]) versus control group (–0.06, SD 0.25 [–0.28; –0.16], p = 0.577). Stage 3 compared with Stage 2: intervention group (−0.60, SD 0.97 [–0.91; –0.29]) versus control group (−0.06, SD 0.25 [–0.15; – 0.03], p = 0.000) |
IRR, incidence rate ratio; SD, standard deviation
Questions on the article in issue 38/2022:
Behavioral Economics Interventions to Improve Medical Decision-Making
The submission deadline is 22 September 2023. Only one answer is possible per question. Please select the answer that is most appropriate.
Question 1
What percentage of premature deaths in industrialized
countries are estimated to be due to preventable behaviors?
approx. 7%
approx. 15%
approx. 30%
approx. 40%
approx. 65%
Question 2
What is the term used to describe teams involved in the science and practice of behavior change in various healthcare organizations?
push units
nudge units
shove units
kick units
prod units
Question 3
When do heuristics significantly affect decision-making?
When complete information and consultation with colleagues are available
At multidisciplinary boards and case conferences
When planning elective surgery
When treating chronic diseases
When under time pressure with incomplete information
Question 4
What is meant by “present bias” when referring to time-inconsistent behavior?
The present matters unduly more than the future
The past matters more than the present
The past matters more than the future
The future matters more than the present
Unpleasant things are done as soon as possible
Question 5
Which term describes preference for the current state of affairs while frequently rejecting alternative options?
loss aversion
present bias
status quo bias
availability bias
laziness bias
Question 6
How much was the reduction in “inappropriate prescriptions for antibiotics” reported in a US study using a self-commitment intervention for “rational prescription of antibiotics”?
approx. 10%
approx. 20%
approx. 30%
approx. 40%
approx. 50%
Question 7
Which term describes the option of rejection in connection with behavioral economics interventions?
opt-in
active choice
objection
opt-out
protest
Question 8
In 2013, the German Society of Internal Medicine introduced an initiative in support of evidence-based decisions to improve patient care. What is this initiative called?
smart decision-making
clever decision-making
quick decision-making
safe decision-making
better decision-making
Question 9
What is the name given to the phenomenon whereby a physician, having previously made a particular diagnosis in one patient, will reach the same diagnosis more often in the future?
performance heuristic
memory heuristic
availability heuristic
recall heuristic
probability heuristic
Question 10
A randomized controlled trial in the USA examined the impact of mandatory decision-making (in the intervention group) with regard to offering screening examinations. Which screening examinations were recommended significantly more often as a result of the intervention and were indeed utilized significantly more often by patients?
mammography
PSA test
colonoscopy
Pap smear
skin cancer screening
Acknowledgments
Translated from the original German by Dr. Grahame Larkin
Acknowledgements Prof. Ockenfels would like to thank the European Research Council (ERC, part of the European Union‘s Horizon 2020 research and innovation program, GA No 741409 – EEC) and the German Research Foundation (DFG, part of the Excellence Strategy of the German Federal and State Governments – EXC 2126/1– 390838866) for supporting his research.
Footnotes
Conflict of interest statement The authors declare thate no conflict of interest exists.
References
- 1.Schroeder SA. We can do better—improving the health of the American people. New Engl J Med. 2007;357:1221–1228. doi: 10.1056/NEJMsa073350. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 2.McGinnis JM, Williams-Russo P, Knickman R. The case for more active policy attention to health promotion. Heal Aff. 2002;21:78–93. doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.21.2.78. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 3.Cawley J, Ruhm CJ. The economics of risky health behaviors. Handbook of Health Economics. 2011;2:95–199. DOI: 10.1016/B978-0-444-53592-4.00003-7. [Google Scholar]
- 4.Ockenfels A. Marktdesign für eine resiliente Impfstoffproduktion. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik. 2021;22:259–269. [Google Scholar]
- 5.Milkman KL, Patel MS, Gandhi L, et al. A megastudy of text-based nudges encouraging patients to get vaccinated at an upcoming doctor’s appointment. Proc Natl Acad Sci. 2021;118 doi: 10.1073/pnas.2101165118. e2101165118. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 6.Frakes M, Gruber J, Jena A. Is great information good enough? Evidence from physicians as patients. J Heal Econ. 2021;75 doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2020.102406. 102406. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 7.Finkelstein A, Persson P, Polyakova M, Shapiro J. A taste of their own medicine: guideline adherence and access to expertise. Am Econ Rev (Insights) 2022 [Google Scholar]
- 8.Downs JS, Loewenstein G, Wisdom J. Strategies for promoting healthier food choices. Am Econ Rev. 2009;99:159–164. doi: 10.1257/aer.99.2.159. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 9.Loewenstein G, Asch DA, Volpp KG. Behavioral economics holds potential to deliver better results for patients, insurers, and employers. Heal Aff. 2013;32:1244–1250. doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.2012.1163. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 10.Patel MS, Volpp KG, Asch DA. Nudge units to improve the delivery of health care. New Engl J Med. 2018;378:214–216. doi: 10.1056/NEJMp1712984. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 11.Blumenthal-Barby JS, Krieger H. Cognitive biases and heuristics in medical decision making: a critical review using a systematic search strategy. Med Decis Mak. 2015;35:539–557. doi: 10.1177/0272989X14547740. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 12.Khullar D, Jha AK, Jena AB. Reducing diagnostic errors—why now? New Engl J Med. 2015;373 doi: 10.1056/NEJMp1508044. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 13.Peters E, Hibbard J, Slovic P, Dieckmann N. Numeracy skill and the communication, comprehension, and use of risk-benefit information. Heal Aff. 2007;26:741–748. doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.26.3.741. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 14.King D, Greaves F, Vlaev I, Darzi A. Approaches based on behavioral economics could help nudge patients and providers toward lower health spending growth. Heal Aff. 2013;32:661–668. doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.2012.1348. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 15.Thaler RH. Behavioral economics: past, present, and future. Am Econ Rev. 2016;106:1577–1600. [Google Scholar]
- 16.Loewenstein G, Asch DA, Volpp KG. Behavioral economics holds potential to deliver better results for patients, insurers, and employers. Heal Aff. 2013;32:1244–1250. doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.2012.1163. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 17.Bolton GE, Ockenfels A. Behavioral economic engineering. J Econ Psychol. 2012;33:665–676. [Google Scholar]
- 18.Chen Y, Cramton P, List JA, Ockenfels A. Market design, human behavior, and management. Manag Sci. 2021;67:5317–5348. [Google Scholar]
- 19.Laibson D. Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Q J Econ. 1997;112:443–478. [Google Scholar]
- 20.O’Donoghue T, Rabin M. Doing it now or later. Am Econ Rev. 1999;89:103–124. [Google Scholar]
- 21.Kahneman D, Tversky A. Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica. 1979;47:263–291. [Google Scholar]
- 22.Sharot T. The optimism bias. Curr Biol. 2011;21:R941–R945. doi: 10.1016/j.cub.2011.10.030. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 23.Tversky A, Kahneman D. Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Science. 1974;185:1124–1131. doi: 10.1126/science.185.4157.1124. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 24.Poses RM, Anthony M. Availability, wishful thinking, and physicians’ diagnostic judgments for patients with suspected bacteremia. Med Decis Mak. 1991;11:159–168. doi: 10.1177/0272989X9101100303. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 25.Samuelson W, Zeckhauser R. Status quo bias in decision making. J Risk Uncertain. 1988;1:7–59. [Google Scholar]
- 26.Patel MS, Day S, Small DS, et al. Using default options within the electronic health record to increase the prescribing of generic-equivalent medications: a quasi-experimental study. Ann Intern Med. 2014;161(10):S44–S52. doi: 10.7326/M13-3001. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 27.Patel MS, Day SC, Halpern SD, et al. Generic medication prescription rates after health system-wide redesign of default options within the electronic health record. JAMA Intern Med. 2016;176:847–848. doi: 10.1001/jamainternmed.2016.1691. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 28.Patel MS, Volpp KG, Small DS, et al. Using active choice within the electronic health record to increase physician ordering and patient completion of high-value cancer screening tests. Healthc (Amst) 2016;4:340–345. doi: 10.1016/j.hjdsi.2016.04.005. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 29.Ockenfels A, Sliwka D, Werner P. Bonus payments and reference point violations. Manag Sci. 2015;61:1496–1513. [Google Scholar]
- 30.Sacarny A, Barnett ML, Le J, Tetkoski F, Yokum D, Agrawal S. Effect of peer comparison letters for high-volume primary care prescribers of quetiapine in older and disabled adults: a randomized clinical trial. JAMA Psychiatry. 2018;75:1003–1011. doi: 10.1001/jamapsychiatry.2018.1867. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 31.Meeker D, Linder JA, Fox CR, et al. Effect of behavioral interventions on inappropriate antibiotic prescribing among primary care practices: a randomized clinical trial. JAMA. 2016;315:562–570. doi: 10.1001/jama.2016.0275. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 32.Hallsworth M, Chadborn T, Sallis A, et al. Provision of social norm feedback to high prescribers of antibiotics in general practice: a pragmatic national randomised controlled trial. Lancet. 2016;387:1743–1752. doi: 10.1016/S0140-6736(16)00215-4. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 33.Eilermann K, Halstenberg K, Kuntz L, Martakis K, Roth B, Wiesen D. The effect of expert feedback on antibiotic prescribing in pediatrics: experimental evidence. Med Decis Mak. 2019;39:781–795. doi: 10.1177/0272989X19866699. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 34.Rogers T, Milkman KL, Volpp KG. Commitment devices: using initiatives to change behavior. JAMA. 2014;311:2065–2066. doi: 10.1001/jama.2014.3485. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 35.Meeker D, Knight TK, Friedberg MW, et al. Nudging guideline-concordant antibiotic prescribing: a randomized clinical trial. JAMA Intern Med. 2014;174:425–431. doi: 10.1001/jamainternmed.2013.14191. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 36.Kullgren JT, Krupka E, Schachter A, et al. Precommitting to choose wisely about low-value services: a stepped wedge cluster randomised trial. BMJ Qual Saf. 2018;27:355–364. doi: 10.1136/bmjqs-2017-006699. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 37.Hasenfuß G, Märker-Herrmann E, Hallek M, Fölsch UR. Initiative “Klug entscheiden”: Gegen Unter- und Überversorgung. Dtsch Arztebl. 2016;113 [Google Scholar]
- 38.Kahneman D, Sibony O, Sunstein CR. Little, Brown & Company. New York: 2021. Noise: a flaw in human judgment. [Google Scholar]
- 39.Ambuehl S, Ockenfels A, Roth AE. Payment in challenge studies from an economics perspective. J Med Ethics. 2020;46:831–832. doi: 10.1136/medethics-2020-106891. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 40.Kübler D, Ockenfels A. Überkreuznierenspenden in Deutschland? Medizinrecht. 2020;38:89–94. [Google Scholar]
- E1.Loewenstein G, Brennan T, Volpp KG. Asymmetric paternalism to improve health behaviors. JAMA. 2007;298:2415–2417. doi: 10.1001/jama.298.20.2415. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E2.Kahneman D. Farrar, Straus and Giroux. New York: 2011. Thinking, fast and slow. [Google Scholar]
- E3.Matjasko JL, Cawley JH, Baker-Goering MM, Yokum DV. Applying behavioral economics to public health policy: illustrative examples and promising directions. Am J Prev Medicine. 2016;50:S13–S19. doi: 10.1016/j.amepre.2016.02.007. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E4.Roberto CA, Kawachi I. Oxford University Press. Oxford: 2015. Behavioral economics and public health. [Google Scholar]
- E5.Hanoch Y, Barnes A, Rice T. Routledge. London: 2017. Behavioral economics and healthy behaviors: key concepts and current research. [Google Scholar]
- E6.Emanuel EJ, Ubel PA, Kessler JB, et al. Using behavioral economics to design physician incentives that deliver high-value care. Ann Intern Med. 2016;164:114–119. doi: 10.7326/M15-1330. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E7.Patel MS, Kurtzman GW, Kannan S, et al. Effect of an automated patient dashboard using active choice and peer comparison performance feedback to physicians on statin prescribing: the prescribe cluster randomized clinical trial. JAMA Netw Open. 2018;1 doi: 10.1001/jamanetworkopen.2018.0818. e180818. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E8.Read D, Van Leeuwen B. Predicting hunger: the effects of appetite and delay on choice. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process. 1998;76:189–205. doi: 10.1006/obhd.1998.2803. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E9.Thaler RH, Sunstein CR. Libertarian paternalism. Am Econ Rev. 2003;93:175–179. [Google Scholar]
- E10.Johnson EJ, Goldstein D. Do defaults save lives? Science. 2003;302:1338–1339. doi: 10.1126/science.1091721. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E11.Carroll GD, Choi JJ, Laibson D, Madrian BC, Metrick A. Optimal defaults and active decisions. Q J Econ. 2009;124:1639–1674. doi: 10.1162/qjec.2009.124.4.1639. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E12.Johnson EJ, Shu SB, Dellaert BGC, et al. Beyond nudges: tools of a choice architecture. Mark Lett. 2012;23:487–504. [Google Scholar]
- E13.Thaler RH. WW Norton. New York: 2015. Misbehaving: The making of behavioral economics. [Google Scholar]
- E14.Halpern SD, Ubel PA, Asch DA. Harnessing the power of default options to improve health care. New Engl J Med. 2007;357:1340–1344. doi: 10.1056/NEJMsb071595. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E15.Patel MS, Volpp KG, Small DS, et al. Using active choice within the electronic health record to increase influenza vaccination rates. J Gen Intern Medicine. 2017;32:790–795. doi: 10.1007/s11606-017-4046-6. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E16.Stutzer A, Goette L, Zehnder M. Active decisions and prosocial behaviour: a field experiment on blood donation. Econ J. 2011;121:F476–F493. [Google Scholar]
- E17.Montoy JCC, Dow WH, Kaplan BC. Patient choice in opt-in, active choice, and opt-out hiv screening: randomized clinical trial. BMJ. 2016;352 doi: 10.1136/bmj.h6895. h6895. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E18.Beshears J, Choi JJ, Laibson D, Madrian BC. Active choice, implicit defaults, and the incentive to choose. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process. 2021;163:6–16. doi: 10.1016/j.obhdp.2019.02.001. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E19.Kiefe CI, Allison JJ, Williams OD, Person SD, Weaver MT, Weissman NW. Improving quality improvement using achievable benchmarks for physician feedback: a randomized controlled trial. JAMA. 2001;285:2871–2879. doi: 10.1001/jama.285.22.2871. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E20.Schultz PW, Nolan JM, Cialdini RB, Goldstein NJ, Griskevicius V. The constructive, destructive, and reconstructive power of social norms. Psychol Sci. 2007;18:429–434. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9280.2007.01917.x. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E21.Cialdini RB, Reno RR, Kallgren CA. A focus theory of normative conduct: recycling the concept of norms to reduce littering in public places. J Pers Soc Psychol. 1990;58 [Google Scholar]
- E22.Persell SD, Doctor JN, Friedberg MW, et al. Behavioral interventions to reduce inappropriate antibiotic prescribing: a randomized pilot trial. BMC Infect Dis. 2016;16 doi: 10.1186/s12879-016-1715-8. 373. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E23.Gine X, Karlan D, Zinman J. Put your money where your butt is: a commitment contract for smoking cessation. Am Econ Journal: Appl Econ. 2010;2:213–235. [Google Scholar]
- E24.Halpern SD, Asch DA, Volpp KG. Commitment contracts as a way to health. BMJ. 2012;344 doi: 10.1136/bmj.e522. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E25.Wang SY, Groene O. The effectiveness of behavioral economics-informed interventions on physician behavioral change: a systematic literature review. PloS One. 2020;15 doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0234149. e0234149. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E26.Waddell KJ, Shah PD, Adusumalli S, Patel MS. Using behavioral economics and technology to improve outcomes in cardio-oncology. JACC CardioOncology. 2020;2:84–96. doi: 10.1016/j.jaccao.2020.02.006. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E27.Galle J. Klug entscheiden: … in der Inneren Medizin. Dtsch Arztebl. 2019;116 A-790-6. [Google Scholar]
- E28.Van Bavel JJ, Baicker K, Boggio PS, et al. Using social and behavioural science to support covid-19 pandemic response. Nat Hum Behav. 2020;4:460–471. doi: 10.1038/s41562-020-0884-z. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E29.Loomba S, de Figueiredo A, Piatek SJ, de Graaf K, Larson HJ. Measuring the impact of covid-19 vaccine misinformation on vaccination intent in the UK and USA. Nat Hum Behav. 2021;5:337–348. doi: 10.1038/s41562-021-01056-1. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E30.Milkman KL. Building trust and battling barriers: The urgent need to overcome vaccine hesitancy. www.//docs.house.gov/meetings/vc/vc00/20210701/112865/hhrg-117-vc00-wstate-milkmanphdk-20210701.pdf. Tech Rep, U.S. House of Representatives Select Subcommittee on the Coronavirus Crisis 2021 (last accessed on 10 February 2022) [Google Scholar]
- E31.Specchia ML, Frisicale EM, Carini E, et al. The impact of tumorboard on cancer care: evidence from an umbrella review. BMC Health Serv Res. 2020;20 doi: 10.1186/s12913-020-4930-3. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E32.Wensing M, Broge B, Riens B, et al. Quality circles to improve prescribing of primary care physicians Three comparative studies. Pharmacoepidemiol Drug Saf. 2009;18:763–769. doi: 10.1002/pds.1778. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E33.Schneider A, Wensing M, Biessecker K, et al. Impact of quality circles for improvement of asthma care: results of a randomized controlled trial. J Eval Clin Pract. 2008;14:185–190. doi: 10.1111/j.1365-2753.2007.00827.x. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E34.Sunstein CR. How change happens. Cambridge: MIT Press. 2019 [Google Scholar]
- E35.Topol EJ. High-performance medicine: the convergence of human and artificial intelligence. Nat Medicine. 2019;25:44–56. doi: 10.1038/s41591-018-0300-7. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E36.Wang, SY, Groene O. The effectiveness of behavioral economics-informed interventions on physician behavioral change: a systematic literature review. PLoS One. 2020;15 doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0234149. e0234149. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E37.Galizzi MM, Wiesen D. Behavioral experiments in health economics Oxford research encyclopedia of economics and finance. https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.244 (last accessed on 10 February 2022) 2018 [Google Scholar]
- E38.Hennig-Schmidt H, Selten R, Wiesen D. How payment systems affect physicians’ provision behaviour—an experimental investigation. J Heal Econ. 2011;30:637–646. doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2011.05.001. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- E39.Brosig-Koch J, Hennig-Schmidt H, Kairies-Schwarz N, Kokot J, Wiesen D. Physician performance pay: experimental evidence. HERO Online Working Paper Series University of Oslo, Health Economics Research Programme 2020. 2020;3 [Google Scholar]
- E40.Waibel C, Wiesen D. An experiment on referrals in health care. Eur Econ Rev. 2021;131 103612. [Google Scholar]
- E41.Huesmann K, Christian CW, Wiesen D. Rankings in healthcare organizationsSemantic Scholar. 2021 doi: 10.2139/ssrn.3690851. [Google Scholar]
- E42.Patel MS, Volpp KG, Asch DA. Nudge units to improve the delivery of health care. New Engl J Med. 2018;378:214–216. doi: 10.1056/NEJMp1712984. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]