Every politician, in every nation and in every era of history, eventually has to face a complex and emotive question. Should I try to redistribute money from my richer citizens to my poorer citizens? If so, by how much? This is a timeless issue. The appropriate answer to the question turns crucially on a claim that goes back hundreds of years to, for example, the philosopher Jeremy Bentham: “All inequality is a source of evil—the inferior loses more in the account of happiness than by the superior is gained.” (1) In an ideal world, a hypothesis of this sort would be tested in a giant randomized controlled trial (RCT), perhaps funded by a body such as the National Science Foundation of the United States. However, no funding body is likely to provide the necessary millions of dollars to run that experiment-until now. In a remarkable and important contribution to conceptual science and practical public policy, Ryan Dwyer and Elizabeth Dunn (2) have—with the help of millionaire donors—run an RCT that comes close to that ideal.
Before the paper by Dwyer and Dunn, a long literature, going back to Richard Easterlin and Edward Diener among others, had established that there is an upward-sloping, although curved, relationship between being richer and saying in a survey that you feel happier. Fig. 1 gives a modern version of the famous pattern.
The Breakthrough Contribution of Dwyer and Dunn Is to Place This Association on Firm Causal Foundations
Dwyer and Dunn create an experiment in which assignment to treatment is random. The authors’ work is an example of a more general movement in modern social science in which earlier correlational research is checked with experimental and quasiexperimental designs (e.g., ref. 3). They add also to an emerging causal literature on cash transfers and well-being in low- and middle-income countries (summarized in, e.g., ref. 4). Dwyer and Dunn deliberately field the same kind of cash transfer in several different economic contexts. In this way, they connect two kinds of literature and demonstrate that cash transfers do indeed improve recipients’ self-reported well-being across a wide variety of settings. There are large causal effects that persist over at least a 6-mo period.
Crucially, in the authors’ experimental research, it is the poorer recipients of (randomly assigned) money who show larger psychological gains. From that, the authors conclude that a reduction in income inequality would raise overall well-being. Their argument has two parts. First, drawing on prior research in the literature (5), Dwyer and Dunn note that the well-being loss incurred by the (millionaire) donors of the cash is likely to be much smaller than the total well-being gains among recipients. Second, the authors discover that the cash transfers’ estimated effect-size appears to decline in a very particular way. It does so linearly in the log of recipients’ income. This is evidence of a curved (concave) well-being-to-income relationship. In other words, as Bentham hypothesized, there are diminishing marginal returns to income.
As is well known—and shown in Fig. 1—a concave relationship between income and well-being entails that wider income inequality will pull down the average level of well-being. This is a corollary of a theorem known as Jensen’s Inequality in mathematics.
Three Scientific Complications Now Stand Out
One complication—formally recognized more than half a century ago (6), but it continues to be hotly debated in political life—is that tax-funded redistribution may distort incentives and thereby dampen economic growth. If so, redistribution could act to raise well-being via a more equal income distribution but at the same time could lower well-being by decreasing the size of the ‘pie’. Assessing the relative importance of these countervailing forces—as discussed in conventional economics courses—remains a priority.
Loss aversion is a second complication. Income losses are known to loom larger than gains. In the short term, therefore, the well-being losses of those who are taxed may exceed the gains of net recipients. Based on earlier work (7), Dwyer and Dunn suggest that voluntarily giving money away can increase people’s well-being. Whether that is also true in the case of forced redistribution is an open question. It may eventually be possible to answer that by building on current studies of loss aversion (such as refs. 8 and 9).
The Third Complication is the Most General
It clearly seems as though Dwyer and Dunn give causal evidence for a curved well-being shape. Yet, as they mention in passing, although they do not elaborate, their paper depends on an untested assumption. It is that the relationship between reported well-being and the underlying actual well-being is linear. Whilst scattered work hints at possible linearity (10–13), nobody currently knows whether that is true. It depends on how humans use language when they answer happiness kinds of questions. This is a particular version of a generalized difficulty outlined in a recent piece by Bond and Lang (14) and previously discussed in Oswald (12). The earlier literature on psychophysics also grappled with this (15). Without knowledge of the ‘reporting function’, we cannot be sure that we can treat well-being data as ratio-scale measurements, which is required for statements like “three times more happiness”.
“Dwyer and Dunn deliberately field the same kind of cash transfer in several different economic contexts. In this way, they connect two literatures and demonstrate that cash transfers do indeed improve recipients’ self-reported wellbeing across a wide variety of settings.”
Let us make the (presumably reasonable) assumption that happier people tend to also report themselves in surveys as happier. Although this is sometimes debated too (14, 16–18), we can then hope to learn about the direction of different influences, like bad illness and higher income, upon subjective well-being. However, it takes more demanding assumptions about the nature of people‘s answers if we are to make robust inferences about curvature, and, more generally, about the relative magnitudes of different influences on well-being. For example, imagine that the income-to-well-being relationship is actually linear and not curved. Yet, now, suppose that people, as they feel cheerier, mark themselves as happier on a questionnaire scale in a way in which they are intrinsically reluctant to approach the upper possible levels on the questionnaire form (the 9 and 10 on a 1–10 scale, say), then the reporting function itself is curved.* Such nonlinearity might occur if respondents treat Likert scales as akin to academic grading systems (19), in which the very top scores are, as in many countries, almost impossible to attain. Another source of nonlinearity might be that people’s potential for suffering may be greater than their capacity for happiness. If so, the bottom scores would cover a wider range of feelings than the top scores. The substantive conclusion in Dwyer and Dunn could be affected in either case.
In a diagram like Fig. 1, the empirical shape linking income and reported well-being actually bundles up two relationships (two equations) into one (12). One relationship is how money affects underlying well-being; the second relationship is how humans report their feelings given any particular level of well-being. There are two relationships, not one—both of these could be curved; neither could be curved; or only one could be curved. Since the welfare-increasing effects of redistribution rely on the idea of that curvature being genuinely about people’s happiness from money, rather than about linguistic cautiousness in people’s use of numbers, we cannot know for certain the degree to which income redistribution might raise actual well-being.
We would like to emphasize that our instinct is that the authors’ finding is correct and that Dwyer and Dunn have written a superb paper of lasting importance. Further research in this area will still be appropriate. It may include qualitative work, perhaps with in-depth interviews on respondents’ scale-use, as well as quantitative work that would systematically map subjective responses to observable cardinal quantities (as in refs. 12 and 15). Currently, the reporting-function problem is fundamental, little recognized, and so far unsolved.
Acknowledgments
Financial support from the Institute for New Economic Thinking through European Research Council Grant Agreement No.856455 is gratefully acknowledged.
Author contributions
C.K. and A.J.O. designed research; C.K. analyzed data; and C.K. and A.J.O. wrote the paper.
Competing interests
Dr. Dwyer (an author of the paper on which this Commentary has been written) has just been hired by a UK-based charity. Coincidentally, one of the board of Trustees of that charity, which are unpaid positions required by English regulatory law, is C.K. We explained this before to PNAS but we record it here also.
Footnotes
*The issue of curved reporting functions is related to, but is conceptually distinct from, concerns about ceiling and floor effects. In the latter case, there is an excess—rather that sparsity—in the share of respondents who select the top and bottom categories. This is often interpreted as a form of data censoring (19).
See companion article, “Wealth redistribution promotes happiness,” 10.1073/pnas.2211123119.
References
- 1.Bentham J., First Principles Preparatory to Constitutional Code (Clarendon Press, 1989). [Google Scholar]
- 2.Dwyer R. J., Dunn E. W., Wealth redistribution promotes happiness. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 119, e2211123119 (2022). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 3.Lindqvist E., Östling R., Cesarini D., Long-run effects of lottery wealth on psychological well-being. Rev. Econ. Stud. 87, 2703–2726 (2020). [Google Scholar]
- 4.McGuire J., Kaiser C., Bach-Mortensen A. M., A systematic review and meta-analysis of the impact of cash transfers on subjective well-being and mental health in low- and middle-income countries. Nat. Hum. Behav. 6, 359–370 (2022). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 5.Donnelly G. E., Zheng T., Haisley E., Norton M. I., The amount and source of millionaires’ wealth (moderately) predict their happiness. Pers. Soc. Psychol. Bull. 44, 684–699 (2018). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 6.Mirrlees J. A., An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Rev. Econ. Stud. 38, 175–208 (1971). [Google Scholar]
- 7.Dunn E. W., Aknin L. B., Norton M. I., Spending money on others promotes happiness. Science 319, 1687–1688 (2008). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 8.Boyce C. J., Wood A. M., Banks J., Clark A. E., Brown G. D., Money, well-being, and loss aversion: Does an income loss have a greater effect on well-being than an equivalent income gain? Psychol. Sci. 24, 2557–2562 (2013). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 9.De Neve J.-E., et al. , The asymmetric experience of positive and negative economic growth: Global evidence using subjective well-being data. Rev. Econ. Stat. 100, 362–375 (2018). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 10.Van Praag B. M. S., Ordinal and cardinal utility: An integration of the two dimensions of the welfare concept. J. Econom. 50, 69–89 (1991). [Google Scholar]
- 11.Layard R., Mayraz G., Nickell S., The marginal utility of income. J. Public Econ. 92, 1846–1857 (2008). [Google Scholar]
- 12.Oswald A. J., On the curvature of the reporting function from objective reality to subjective feelings. Econ. Lett. 100, 369–372 (2008). [Google Scholar]
- 13.Kaiser C., Oswald A. J., The scientific value of numerical measures of human feelings. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 119, e2210412119 (2022). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 14.Bond T. N., Lang K., The sad truth about happiness scales. J. Polit. Econ. 127, 1629–1640 (2019). [Google Scholar]
- 15.Banks W. P., Coleman M. J., Two subjective scales of number. Percept. Psychophys. 29, 95–105 (1981). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 16.Schröder C., Yitzhaki S., Revisiting the evidence for cardinal treatment of ordinal variables. Eur. Econ. Rev. 92, 337–358 (2017). [Google Scholar]
- 17.Bloem J. R., How much does the cardinal treatment of ordinal variables matter? An empirical investigation. Polit. Anal. 30, 1–17 (2021), 10.1017/pan.2020.55. [DOI] [Google Scholar]
- 18.Kaiser C., Vendrik M., How threatening are transformations of happiness scales to subjective wellbeing research? INET Oxford Working Paper No. 2020-19. (2022). https://www.inet.ox.ac.uk/files/happytransformations_for_WP.pdf
- 19.Marquez-Padilla F., Alvarez J., Grading happiness: What grading systems tell us about cross-country wellbeing comparisons. Econ. Bull. 38, 1138–1155 (2018). [Google Scholar]
- 20.Liu Q., Wang L., t-Test and ANOVA for data with ceiling and/or floor effects. Behav. Res. Methods 53, 264–277 (2021). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]