Significance
How large-scale cooperation, observed mainly in human societies, is maintained has long been of wide interest and studied by indirect reciprocity models, where individuals choose their behavior based on the reputation of the partner and judge observed actions of others as good or bad. Recent studies show, however, that, when individuals cannot share their evaluations of others (called private assessment), mismatches in their opinions are amplified and eventually collapse their proper judgments of good and bad individuals. This study theoretically shows that cooperation is stable even under such noisy and private assessment. We find that a key to success is moderate simplicity in the rule of reputation assignment.
Keywords: cooperation, indirect reciprocity, private assessment, simple standing
Abstract
Indirect reciprocity is a mechanism that explains large-scale cooperation in humans. In indirect reciprocity, individuals use reputations to choose whether or not to cooperate with a partner and update others’ reputations. A major question is how the rules to choose their actions and the rules to update reputations evolve. In the public reputation case where all individuals share the evaluation of others, social norms called Simple Standing (SS) and Stern Judging (SJ) have been known to maintain cooperation. However, in the case of private assessment where individuals independently evaluate others, the mechanism of maintenance of cooperation is still largely unknown. This study theoretically shows for the first time that cooperation by indirect reciprocity can be evolutionarily stable under private assessment. Specifically, we find that SS can be stable, but SJ can never be. This is intuitive because SS can correct interpersonal discrepancies in reputations through its simplicity. On the other hand, SJ is too complicated to avoid an accumulation of errors, which leads to the collapse of cooperation. We conclude that moderate simplicity is a key to stable cooperation under the private assessment. Our result provides a theoretical basis for the evolution of human cooperation.
Cooperation benefits others but is costly to the cooperator itself. Nevertheless, cooperation is widespread from microscopic to macroscopic scales, such as among microorganisms, animals, humans, and nations. One way to sustain cooperation is that agents conditionally cooperate with others who cooperate with them, which is realized by, for example, repeated interactions (1–3) and partner choice (4–7). Such conditional cooperation based on personal experiences is applicable only to a small population where members can interact directly and repeatedly with most of the others.
However, cooperative behavior is observed even in a large-scale society (e.g., human societies). Since individuals inevitably encounter strangers there, they need the reputations of those strangers in order not to cooperate unconditionally. The mechanism where individuals indirectly reward others via their reputations as described above is called indirect reciprocity (8–10). In reality, humans are particularly interested in reputations and gossip about themselves and others (11–13). Furthermore, many experiments have pointed out that gossips concern cooperative behaviors (14–16).
Errors that inevitably occur in actions and in assessments hinder cooperation by indirect reciprocity. Indeed, the simplest social norm called image scoring (9, 10) fails to maintain full cooperation under errors (17, 18) [a similar failure is also seen in direct reciprocity (18–20)]. This is because one erroneous defection triggers further defection. Nevertheless, previous studies have theoretically shown that cooperation can be maintained by the so-called “leading eight” social norms (21, 22) even in the presence of such errors when all individuals share the reputation of the same individual (i.e., public reputation). Public reputation cases have been thoroughly studied for about two decades (23–37). When individuals cannot share their evaluations of the same target (i.e., private assessment), however, errors cast a shadow over cooperation more crucially. In this case, a single disagreement in opinions between two individuals can lead to further disagreements (38–42). Whether cooperation is maintained under such noisy and private assessment is still largely unsolved in theory and is one of the major open problems in studies of indirect reciprocity (36, 43, 44).
Previous studies have shown that maintaining cooperation with indirect reciprocity is very difficult under noisy and private assessment. For example, Hilbe et al. (42) showed by an evolutionary simulation that the above leading eight strategies cannot succeed in cooperation under private assessment. Some studies (45–47) have demonstrated the emergence of cooperation under noisy and private assessment, but under the restrictive assumption that only local mutations in the strategy space are allowed, thus excluding the possibility that a fully cooperative strategy is directly invaded by free riders. Other studies have shown that a mechanism to synchronize opinions between individuals has a positive influence on cooperation in indirect reciprocity, such as empathy, generosity, spatial structure, and so on (48–57).
Most of these studies of private assessment have been performed by computer simulations (42, 45). This is because two-dimensional information of who assigns a reputation to whom [its matrix representation is called “image matrix” (38, 39, 58, 59)] becomes too complex to analyze. For example, its possible transition is illustrated in Fig. 1A, where a single assessment error can be amplified with time, leading to a mosaic structure in the image matrix. Previously, the authors have developed an analytical approach (60) to study the image matrix, but it was applicable only when the population is monomorphic in strategies. However, for an evolutionary analysis between wild type and mutant, we need a different method because the image matrix now includes four compartments based on different rules of reputation assignment adopted by wild-type and mutant individuals (Fig. 1B). In spite of these difficulties, here we report that we have successfully developed a new analytical machinery to study the image matrix, which has been obtained by qualitatively extending the previous approach. This enables us to make a general prediction of when cooperation is sustained under noisy and private assessment over the full parameter region.
In the following, we will first introduce the setting of indirect reciprocity under noisy and private assessment and explain a method to analytically calculate an expected payoff of each individual through analyzing an image matrix. Then, we will discuss which strategy can be an evolutionarily stable strategy (ESS) (61, 62) under which condition and provide intuitive reasons for the result. To our knowledge, this is the first systematic study that has analytically investigated evolutionary stability of strategies in indirect reciprocity under noisy and private assessment.
Model
We consider a model of indirect reciprocity in a well-mixed population of size N. We assume that, in every step, a binary reputation is assigned independently from everyone to everyone, either good or bad, which is summarized by image matrix {βji}, where βji = 1 (resp. βji = 0) if individual i assigns a good (resp. bad) reputation to individual j. The model proceeds as follows. First, a donor and a recipient are randomly chosen from this population. Next, the donor takes its action, cooperation, or defection to the recipient. When the donor cooperates, the donor incurs a cost c(> 0) but gives a benefit b(> c) to the recipient instead. On the other hand, when the donor defects, no change occurs in the payoff of the donor or the recipient. Here, a rule that specifies how the donor chooses its action is called “action rule”. Throughout this paper, we assume that all the individuals adopt the “discriminator” action rule (9, 63), with which they choose cooperation (resp. defection) to a good (resp. bad) recipient in their own eyes; that is, donor i chooses cooperation toward recipient j if βji = 1 and chooses defection if βji = 0. We assume that the donor unintentionally takes the opposite action to the intended one with probability 0 ≤ e1 < 1/2 (action error). All the individuals in the population observe this social interaction between the donor and the recipient and independently update the reputation of the donor in their eyes. We assume that these processes of action choice and reputation update continue sufficiently long time (i.e., continuation probability is 1).
A rule that specifies how each observer updates reputations is called its “social norm”. In models of public reputation, it has often been assumed that all the individuals in the population adopt the same social norm (21, 29, 64) (but ref. 38), otherwise they cannot share the reputation of the same individual. Because we consider a model of private reputation here, however, we instead assume that individuals can adopt different social norms. This study deals with a situation where each observer (say, k) refers to (i) whether the donor (say, i) cooperates (C) or defects (D) (first-order information) and (ii) whether the recipient (say, j) is good (G) or bad (B) in the eyes of the observer (second-order information, represented by βjk) when this observer updates the reputation of the donor in the eyes of the observer, denoted by βik. Such social norms are called “second-order” social norms (10, 18, 33, 36). An observer who adopts a second-order social norm can face four different cases, denoted by GC(“toward a Good recipient the donor Cooperates”), BC(“toward a Bad recipient the donor Cooperates”), GD(“toward a Good recipient the donor Defects”), and BD(“toward a Bad recipient the donor Defects”), respectively, and in each case, the observer assigns either a good (G) or bad (B) reputation to the donor. Thus, a social norm is represented by a four-letter string. For example, GBBG is the social norm that assigns to the donor a good reputation in GC- and BD-cases and a bad reputation in BC- and GD-cases. There are 24 = 16 such social norms in total, and we lexicographically order them with the rule that G comes first and B comes second and number them from S01 to S16. Table 1 shows a full list of 16 social norms studied here. When updating the reputation, each observer independently commits an assessment error with probability 0 < e2 < 1/2, in which case he/she accidentally assigns the opposite reputation to the intended one to the donor.
Table 1.
Social norm | GC | BC | GD | BD | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
S 01 | (ALLG) | G | G | G | G |
S 02 | G | G | G | B | |
S 03 | (SS; Simple Standing) | G | G | B | G |
S 04 | (SC; Scoring) | G | G | B | B |
S 05 | G | B | G | G | |
S 06 | G | B | G | B | |
S 07 | (SJ; Stern Judging) | G | B | B | G |
S 08 | (SH; Shunning) | G | B | B | B |
S 09 | B | G | G | G | |
S 10 | B | G | G | B | |
S 11 | B | G | B | G | |
S 12 | B | G | B | B | |
S 13 | B | B | G | G | |
S 14 | B | B | G | B | |
S 15 | B | B | B | G | |
S 16 | (ALLB) | B | B | B | B |
Several norms are especially important in previous studies, so we explain them below. We call S01 ALLG and call S16 ALLB because these norms unconditionally assign good or bad reputations. Next, S03, S04, S07, and S08 belong to G*B* family. These norms share the same feature that they regard cooperation toward a good recipient as good and defection toward a good recipient as bad. They only differ when the recipient is bad in the observer’s eyes. First, S04 is called Scoring (SC), which regards cooperation toward a bad recipient as good and defection toward a bad recipient as bad, and therefore, reputation assignment is independent of whether the recipient is good or bad in the observer’s eyes (thus, categorized as a first-order norm). Next, S07 is called Stern Judging (SJ), which regards cooperation toward a bad recipient as bad and defection toward a bad recipient as good, as opposed to SC. Third, S03 is called Simple Standing (SS) and it regards any action toward a bad recipient as good, and therefore, it is the most generous norm in this family. Finally, S08 is called Shunning (SH) and it regards any action toward a bad recipient as bad, and therefore, it is the most intolerant one. Notably, SJ and SS are the two second-order norms that are included in the “leading eight” norms (21), which can successfully maintain cooperation under noisy and public assessment within third-order norms. In particular, SJ has long been considered promising because it is evolutionarily successful (23) and because it sustains a very high level of cooperation despite its simplicity (33, 36). SJ always suggests only one correct action to keep you good; it recommends cooperation toward good individuals and defection toward bad ones, and failure to follow this rule leads to a bad reputation. Under the noisy public reputation, SH cannot achieve full cooperation against itself but can prevent the invasion of ALLB (SI Appendix for detailed calculations).
Under these settings, the strategy of an individual is its social norm. For this reason, we use “strategy” and “(social) norm” interchangeably in the following. We ask which strategy is evolutionarily stable. To this end, we study invasibility of a mutant strategy against a wild-type one. A strategy is ESS if it is not invaded by any other 15 mutant strategies. To derive their payoffs, we need to analyze the image matrix, which we shall perform below.
Analysis of Reputation Structure
Let us consider a situation where individuals with mutant norm M invade the population of wild-type norm W (≠ M). Here, the proportion of mutants is given by δ. By extending the methodology in Fujimoto and Ohtsuki (60), who studied private reputation structure in a monomorphic population, here, we have developed a new framework to analyze the structure of private reputations in a dimorphic population where wild types and mutants coexist (SI Appendix for detailed calculations). Specifically, take a focal individual whose norm is A ∈ {W, M}, and let pAA′ (hereafter called “goodness”) be the proportion of individuals among norm A′ users who assign a good reputation to the focal individual, for A′∈{W, M}. Thus, a wild-type individual is characterized by a pair of goodnesses, (pWW, pWM), and we represent its joint probability distribution over all wild-type individuals by ΦW(pWW, pWM). In the same way, a mutant is characterized by a pair of goodnesses, (pMW, pMM), and ΦM(pMW, pMM) represents its distribution over all mutants. In SI Appendix, we derive the dynamics of ΦW and ΦM by formulating a stochastic transition of the donor’s goodnesses under the assumption of N ≫ 1 (the population is large), δ ≪ 1 (mutants are rare), and Nδ ≫ 1 (yet, the number of mutants is sufficiently large). Since we assume that the continuation probability is 1, we derive their equilibrium distributions, and , in order to calculate expected payoffs of wild types and mutants, which enable us to study the invasibility condition of mutants to wild types (SI Appendix again).
We find that each of the two equilibrium distributions is well approximated by a weighted sum of two-dimensional Gaussian functions with zero covariance, where each Gaussian can be systematically labeled by a nonzero integer, j ∈ ℤ ∖ {0} (see an example in Fig. 2B and the rule of labeling in Fig. 2C). Hence, the number of Gaussians that appear in the sum is infinitely but countably many, but in some cases, these labels degenerate (i.e., two or more Gaussians are identical but they are given different labels) and it can be finite. Weights to Gaussians decay exponentially as j becomes large positive or large negative, so a truncation at some finite number of terms approximates well the infinite sum for numerical calculations.
ESS Norms
Based on the analysis of the image matrix above, we have studied pairwise invasibility for all the pairs of wild-type W and mutant M. In the following, we set the action error rate as e1 = 0 because this error, especially when it is small positive, does not have a qualitative impact on our results as far as we studied. Thus, the cost-benefit ratio b/c and the assessment error rate e2 are our environmental parameters.
We first find that the four strategies, S06, S07(SJ), S10, and S11, are completely indistinguishable, both as wild type and as mutant. This is because these norms always give the goodness of 1/2 to anyone in the population at equilibrium due to an accumulation of assessment errors and hence they appear to choose cooperation and defection in a random manner (this has been known for S07(SJ); refs. 38, 39, and 42). In particular, they are neutral to each other. For these reasons, we will discuss only S07(SJ) as a representative of them and exclude the other three in the following analysis.
Our exhaustive analysis demonstrates that only three norms, S03(SS), S08(SH), and S16(ALLB), can be ESS, and all the others cannot. As shown in Fig. 3A, ALLB is ESS independent of b/c and e2 because it is the norm that assigns a bad reputation to everyone, saves the own cost, and provides no benefit to others. On the other hand, SS and SH achieve ESS for some b/c and e2; there are upper and lower bounds of b/c for them to be ESS, which depend on e2. Below we will look at its details.
Conditions for ESS
The ESS condition of S03(SS) is shown in Fig. 3B. When b/c exceeds the upper bound, the norm is invaded by S01(ALLG) (compare the Right and Center panels of Fig. 3A). On the other hand, when b/c falls below the lower bound, the norm is invaded by S04(SC) (compare the Left and Center panels of Fig. 3A). Fig. 3C shows that these theoretical bounds are also supported by individual-based simulations. Notably, the smaller e2 is, the wider the ESS region of S03(SS) becomes.
The ESS region of S08(SH) is quite narrow in comparison to that of S03(SS), as seen in Fig. 3B. In addition, when b/c exceeds the upper bound or falls below the lower bound, the norm is invaded by S04(SC) and S16(ALLB), respectively. The range of b/c-ratios that make SH evolutionarily stable is widest at an intermediate e2 (about 0.1).
In contrast to these results, we find that S07(SJ), which is known to be a successful norm when reputation is public, is invaded by norms such as S16(ALLB) and S08(SH) independent of the value of b/c (and also independent of e2) and therefore that it is never an ESS. This is summarized in Fig. 3A.
To summarize, SS, SH, and SJ are all the ESS norms under the public reputation, but whether they remain ESS under the private assessment critically differs. This difference is clearly understood by focusing on how the reputation structure they give differs between the public and private reputation cases under a sufficiently small but positive assessment error rate, e2 ≪ 1. Let us consider below, for example, whether each norm can prevent the invasion of ALLB, a potential invader norm.
Success of Simple Standing.
The reputation structure that S03(SS) gives differs little between the public and private reputation cases (Fig. 3D). Under the public reputation (SI Appendix for the calculation), SS assigns good reputations to SS themselves (represented by the bar at goodness =1 in the Top-Left panel in Fig. 3D), while bad reputations to ALLB (represented by the bar at goodness =0 in the Top-Right panel in Fig. 3D). Thus, SS distinguishes between SS itself and the invader ALLB and prevents the invasion of ALLB. Even under the private reputation, SS still assigns good reputations to SS themselves (Bottom-Left panel in Fig. 3; high goodness of 1 − e2 are given to the fraction 1 − 2e2 of SS individuals, for example) and assigns bad reputations to ALLB (Bottom-Right panel in Fig. 3; low goodness of 2e2 are given to the fraction 1 − 3e2 of ALLB individuals, for example). Thus, the distinction between SS and ALLB is maintained. For that reason, SS succeeds in achieving ESS even under the private assessment. The cooperation rate at this ESS is as high as 1 − 2e2 for small e2, so it entails nearly perfect cooperation.
Failure of Stern Judging.
Contrary to SS, the reputation structure that S07(SJ) gives extremely differs between the public and private reputation cases (Fig. 3E). Under the public reputation (SI Appendix for the calculation), wild-type SJ gives high goodness to other SJ (Top-Left in Fig. 3E) and wild-type SJ gives low goodness to ALLB (Top-Right in Fig. 3E). Thus, SJ prevents the invasion of ALLB. Under the private assessment, however, SJ gives the goodness of 1/2 to other SJ individuals (Bottom-Left in Fig. 3E) (38, 39, 42), while SJ gives the goodness of 1/2 to ALLB individuals as well (Bottom-Right in Fig. 3E). Thus, the distinction between SJ and ALLB is lost. This is why SJ fails to be ESS under the private assessment.
Shunning Can Be ESS, but the Level of Cooperation Is Low.
We can understand why S08(SH) achieves ESS only in a narrow region under private reputation (SI Appendix for the detailed calculation and SI Appendix, Fig. S3 for the illustration for easy interpretation). Under the public reputation, SH gives good reputations to half of other SH wild types and bad reputations to the other half (Top-Left in SI Appendix, Fig. S3) while SH gives bad reputations to almost all ALLB (Top-Right in SI Appendix, Fig. S3). Thus, SH prevents the invasion of ALLB. Under private reputation, on the other hand, SH gives low goodness to both SH and ALLB (Bottom-Left and Bottom-Right in SI Appendix, Fig. S3). Here, however, SH has a slightly better chance to receive good reputations than ALLB, in the order of e22. This explains why SH prevents the invasion from ALLB only in a narrow region and also explains why its ESS condition becomes more strict for a smaller assessment error rate, e2. The cooperation rate at a realized ESS is as low as e2 for small e2, so we conclude that S08(SH) does not contribute to cooperation.
Discussion
This study considered indirect reciprocity under noisy and private assessment. We focused on the goodness of an individual (i.e., what proportion of individuals assigns the focal individual a good reputation) between different norms and developed an analytical method to calculate the distribution of goodness at equilibrium. Using this methodology, we studied whether a mutant norm succeeds in the invasion into a wild-type norm. As far as we know, this is the first analytical study that exhaustively investigated the evolutionary stability of all possible second-order social norms under noisy and private assessment. Although both S03(SS) and S07(SJ) can be ESS under public reputation, we found that their evolutionary stability is totally different under private assessment. In particular, we found that S03(SS) remains to be ESS under private assessment if the assessment error rate is small, while S07(SJ) cannot be ESS no matter how small the error rate is (38, 39, 42).
The reason for this difference between S03(SS) and S07(SJ) comes from the difference in the complexity of these two norms. In the world of private assessment, errors in assessment accumulate independently among observers, which is a potential source of collapse of cooperation in the population. However, since S03(SS) regards a cooperating donor as good no matter whether the recipient is good or bad, discrepancy in the opinion toward the recipient between two different observers does not produce further discrepancy; those two observers can agree that such a cooperating donor is good. In contrast, S07(SJ) is more complex than S03(SS) and the recipient’s reputation is always decisive information (Table 1), so this complexity becomes an obstacle for correcting discrepancy between observers.
Hilbe et al. (42) studied by computer simulations whether the leading eight norms can sustain cooperation under the noisy and private assessment. They concluded that S03(SS) (referred to as “L3” in their paper) and S07(SJ) (“L6”) fail to achieve cooperation, which is contrary to our result. This difference is partly because we studied evolutionary stability in a deterministic model, while they studied fixation probability in a stochastic model. Because those two criteria are different, drawing a general conclusion is difficult. For example, our ESS analysis cannot fully answer how robust each ESS is compared to others, although we can calculate the payoff difference between a focal ESS (as wild type) and a mutant strategy, which indicates its robustness to some extent. For a full understanding of the system, it would be ideal to extend our current framework so that we can study a wild-type/mutant system where mutants are not necessarily rare. Such an extension will enable us to study an invasion barrier (65), that is the maximal frequency of mutants that wild types can resist, and to discuss the robustness of each ESS in a higher resolution. We leave it as a future study.
Our current study assumed that everyone adopts the discriminator action rule. This approach was taken in a previous study (45) to make the analysis tractable. One can conceive, however, three other possible action rules such as “ALLC” that always cooperates, “ALLD” that always defects, and “paradoxical discriminator” (30, 64) that cooperates with a bad individual and defects with a good one. Nevertheless, our current approach retains fairly good generality. First, studying a paradoxical discriminator with a norm Si is mathematically equivalent to studying a discriminator with a norm S17 − i because these two norms are symmetric to each other with respect to G and B reputations (Table 1). Second, ALLC essentially corresponds to ALLG because ALLG always intends to assign a good reputation to others and cooperate with them, and ALLD essentially corresponds to ALLB because ALLB always intends to assign a bad reputation and defect with them. Strictly speaking, a difference arises between ALLC and ALLG and between ALLD and ALLB when there is an assessment error, but we believe that our choice of strategy space is reasonable, especially when this error rate is small.
A future direction of this study would be to examine ESS conditions of social norms when some of the assumptions are changed. For example, we have assumed second-order norms, in which individuals refer to a donor’s action (first-order information) and a recipient’s reputation (second-order one) when they update the donor’s reputation. However, humans may use more complex norms than second-order ones. Studying the effect of higher-order information (32, 33, 36, 66), such as the previous reputation of the donor (third-order information), would further deepen our understanding. We have also assumed that all individuals simultaneously update their opinions toward the same donor. However, in a real society, the number of people who can observe a single person’s behavior is limited. Thus, the effect of asynchronous updates of reputations is worth studying. Last but not least, we have assumed that game interactions last sufficiently long so that we can use equilibrium distributions of goodness for calculating payoffs. This assumption was helpful for our analysis because we can neglect any effects of the initial condition. We admit that it was the most favorable condition for cooperation. Studying a model with continuation probability being less than 1, as in refs. 9, 17, 18, and 29, is important because such a model is more realistic.
In conclusion, we have demonstrated that cooperation can be evolutionarily stable even under noisy and private assessment. Specifically, we have shown that Stern Judging, which is one of the leading norms under public reputation, cannot distinguish between cooperators and defectors under private assessment and thus fails to achieve ESS. On the other hand, we have revealed that Simple Standing can be stable in a wide range of parameters. Based on these results, we predict that Simple Standing should play a key role in sustaining cooperation by indirect reciprocity under noisy private assessment. These findings provide a rigid theoretical basis for understanding human cooperation and pave the way for future studies in biology, psychology, sociology, and economics.
Supplementary Material
Acknowledgments
Y.F. acknowledges the support by JSPS KAKENHI Grant No. JP21J01393. H.O. acknowledges the support by JSPS KAKENHI Grant No. JP19H04431.
Author contributions
Y.F. and H.O. designed research; performed research; and wrote the paper.
Competing interests
The authors declare no competing interest.
Footnotes
This article is a PNAS Direct Submission.
Data, Materials, and Software Availability
There are no data underlying this work.
Supporting Information
References
- 1.Trivers R. L., The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Q. Rev. Biol. 46, 35–57 (1971). [Google Scholar]
- 2.Axelrod R., Hamilton W. D., The evolution of cooperation. Science 211, 1390–1396 (1981). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 3.Axelrod R., The Evolution of Cooperation (Basic, New York, 1984). [Google Scholar]
- 4.T. Yamagishi, N. Hayashi, N. Jin, “Prisoner’s dilemma networks: Selection strategy versus action strategy” in Social Dilemmas and Cooperation (Springer, 1984), pp. 233–250.
- 5.Noë R., Hammerstein P., Biological markets: Supply and demand determine the effect of partner choice in cooperation, mutualism and mating. Behav. Ecol. Sociobiol. 35, 1–11 (1994). [Google Scholar]
- 6.Noë R., Hammerstein P., Biological markets. Trends Ecol. Evol. 10, 336–339 (1995). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 7.Barclay P., Strategies for cooperation in biological markets, especially for humans. Evol. Hum. Behav. 34, 164–175 (2013). [Google Scholar]
- 8.Alexander R. D., The Biology of Moral Systems (Aldine de Gruyter, New York, 1987). [Google Scholar]
- 9.Nowak M. A., Sigmund K., Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nature 393, 573–577 (1998). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 10.Nowak M. A., Sigmund K., Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature 437, 1291–1298 (2005). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 11.N. Emler, Gossip, Reputation, and Social Adaptation (University Press of Kansas, 1994).
- 12.R. I. M. Dunbar, Grooming, Gossip, and the Evolution of Language (Harvard University Press, 1998).
- 13.Dunbar R. I., Gossip in evolutionary perspective. Rev. General Psychol. 8, 100–110 (2004). [Google Scholar]
- 14.Feinberg M., Willer R., Stellar J., Keltner D., The virtues of gossip: Reputational information sharing as prosocial behavior. J. Personality Soc. Psychol. 102, 1015 (2012). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 15.Feinberg M., Willer R., Schultz M., Gossip and ostracism promote cooperation in groups. Psychol. Sci. 25, 656–664 (2014). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 16.Wu J., Balliet D., Van Lange P. A., Reputation, gossip, and human cooperation. Soc. Personality Psychol. Compass 10, 350–364 (2016). [Google Scholar]
- 17.Panchanathan K., Boyd R., A tale of two defectors: The importance of standing for evolution of indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 224, 115–126 (2003). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 18.K. Sigmund, The Calculus of Selfishness (Princeton University Press, 2010).
- 19.Nowak M., Sigmund K., A strategy of win-stay, lose-shift that outperforms tit-for-tat in the prisoner’s dilemma game. Nature 364, 56–58 (1993). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 20.Wu J., Axelrod R., How to cope with noise in the iterated prisoner’s dilemma. J. Conf. Resol. 39, 183–189 (1995). [Google Scholar]
- 21.Ohtsuki H., Iwasa Y., How should we define goodness? Reputation dynamics in indirect reciprocity J. Theor. Biol. 231, 107–120 (2004). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 22.Ohtsuki H., Iwasa Y., The leading eight: Social norms that can maintain cooperation by indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 239, 435–444 (2006). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 23.Pacheco J. M., Santos F. C., Chalub F. A. C., Stern-judging: A simple, successful norm which promotes cooperation under indirect reciprocity. PLoS Comput. Biol. 2, e178 (2006). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 24.Suzuki S., Akiyama E., Evolution of indirect reciprocity in groups of various sizes and comparison with direct reciprocity. J. Theore. Biol. 245, 539–552 (2007). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 25.F. C. Santos, F. A. Chalub, J. M. Pacheco, “A multi-level selection model for the emergence of social norms” in European Conference on Artificial Life (Springer, 2007), pp. 525–534.
- 26.Fu F., Hauert C., Nowak M. A., Wang L., Reputation-based partner choice promotes cooperation in social networks. Phys. Rev. E 78, 026117 (2008). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 27.Suzuki S., Akiyama E., Evolutionary stability of first-order-information indirect reciprocity in sizable groups. Theore. Popul. Biol. 73, 426–436 (2008). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 28.Uchida S., Sigmund K., The competition of assessment rules for indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 263, 13–19 (2010). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 29.Ohtsuki H., Iwasa Y., Nowak M. A., Reputation effects in public and private interactions. PLoS Comput. Biol. 11, e1004527 (2015). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 30.Santos F. P., Santos F. C., Pacheco J. M., Social norms of cooperation in small-scale societies. PLoS Comput. Biol. 12, e1004709 (2016). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 31.Santos F. P., Pacheco J. M., Santos F. C., Evolution of cooperation under indirect reciprocity and arbitrary exploration rates. Sci. Rep. 6, 1–9 (2016). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 32.Sasaki T., Okada I., Nakai Y., The evolution of conditional moral assessment in indirect reciprocity. Sci. Rep. 7, 1–8 (2017). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 33.Santos F. P., Santos F. C., Pacheco J. M., Social norm complexity and past reputations in the evolution of cooperation. Nature 555, 242–245 (2018). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 34.F. Santos, J. Pacheco, F. Santos, “Social norms of cooperation with costly reputation building” in Proceedings of the AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence (2018), vol. 32.
- 35.Xia C., Gracia-Lázaro C., Moreno Y., Effect of memory, intolerance, and second-order reputation on cooperation. Chaos: Interdiscip. J. Nonlinear Sci. 30, 063122 (2020). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 36.Santos F. P., Pacheco J. M., Santos F. C., The complexity of human cooperation under indirect reciprocity. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. B 376, 20200291 (2021). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 37.Podder S., Righi S., Takács K., Local reputation, local selection, and the leading eight norms. Sci. Rep. 11, 1–10 (2021). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 38.Uchida S., Effect of private information on indirect reciprocity. Phys. Rev. E 82, 036111 (2010). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 39.Uchida S., Sasaki T., Effect of assessment error and private information on stern-judging in indirect reciprocity. Chaos, Solitons Fractals 56, 175–180 (2013). [Google Scholar]
- 40.Okada I., Sasaki T., Nakai Y., Tolerant indirect reciprocity can boost social welfare through solidarity with unconditional cooperators in private monitoring. Sci. Rep. 7, 1–11 (2017). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 41.Okada I., Sasaki T., Nakai Y., A solution for private assessment in indirect reciprocity using solitary observation. J. Theor. Biol. 455, 7–15 (2018). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 42.Hilbe C., Schmid L., Tkadlec J., Chatterjee K., Nowak M. A., Indirect reciprocity with private, noisy, and incomplete information. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 115, 12241–12246 (2018). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 43.S. Bowles, H. Gintis, A Cooperative Species (Princeton University Press, 2011).
- 44.Okada I., A review of theoretical studies on indirect reciprocity. Games 11, 27 (2020). [Google Scholar]
- 45.Yamamoto H., Okada I., Uchida S., Sasaki T., A norm knockout method on indirect reciprocity to reveal indispensable norms. Sci. Rep. 7, 1–7 (2017). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 46.Lee S., Murase Y., Baek S. K., Local stability of cooperation in a continuous model of indirect reciprocity. Sci. Rep. 11, 1–13 (2021). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 47.S. Lee, Y. Murase, S. K. Baek, A second-order stability analysis for the continuous model of indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 548, 111202. (2022). [DOI] [PubMed]
- 48.Brush E., Brännström Å., Dieckmann U., Indirect reciprocity with negative assortment and limited information can promote cooperation. J. Theor. Biol. 443, 56–65 (2018). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 49.Whitaker R. M., Colombo G. B., Rand D. G., Indirect reciprocity and the evolution of prejudicial groups. Sci. Rep. 8, 1–14 (2018). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 50.Radzvilavicius A. L., Stewart A. J., Plotkin J. B., Evolution of empathetic moral evaluation. Elife 8, e44269 (2019). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 51.M. Krellner, T. A. Han, “Putting oneself in everybody’s shoes-pleasing enables indirect reciprocity under private assessments” in Artificial Life Conference Proceedings 32 (MIT Press One Rogers Street, Cambridge, MA 02142-1209, USA, 2020), pp. 402–410.
- 52.Quan J., et al. , Withhold-judgment and punishment promote cooperation in indirect reciprocity under incomplete information. EPL (Europhys. Lett.) 128, 28001 (2020). [Google Scholar]
- 53.Krellner M., Han T. A., Pleasing enhances indirect reciprocity-based cooperation under private assessment. Artif. Life 31, 1–31 (2021). [Google Scholar]
- 54.Schmid L., Shati P., Hilbe C., Chatterjee K., The evolution of indirect reciprocity under action and assessment generosity. Sci. Rep. 11, 1–14 (2021). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 55.T. A. Kessinger, J. B. Plotkin, Indirect reciprocity in populations with group structure. arXiv [Preprint] (2022). http://arxiv.org/abs/2204.10811 (Accessed 25 January 2023).
- 56.Quan J., Nie J., Chen W., Wang X., Keeping or reversing social norms promote cooperation by enhancing indirect reciprocity. Chaos, Solitons Fractals 158, 111986 (2022). [Google Scholar]
- 57.P. Gu, Y. Zhang, “Reputation-based rewiring promotes cooperation in complex network” in Advances in Guidance, Navigation and Control (Springer, 2022), pp. 1405–1415.
- 58.Sigmund K., Moral assessment in indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 299, 25–30 (2012). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 59.Oishi K., Shimada T., Ito N., Group formation through indirect reciprocity. Phys. Rev. E 87, 030801 (2013). [Google Scholar]
- 60.Fujimoto Y., Ohtsuki H., Reputation structure in indirect reciprocity under noisy and private assessment. Sci. Rep. 12, 1–13 (2022). [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 61.Maynard-Smith J., Price G. R., The logic of animal conflict. Nature 246, 15–18 (1973). [Google Scholar]
- 62.J. Maynard-Smith, Evolution and the Theory of Games (Cambridge University Press, 1982).
- 63.Nowak M. A., Sigmund K., The dynamics of indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 194, 561–574 (1998). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 64.Ohtsuki H., Iwasa Y., Global analyses of evolutionary dynamics and exhaustive search for social norms that maintain cooperation by reputation. J. Theor. Biol. 244, 518–531 (2007). [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- 65.J. Hofbauer, K. Sigmund, Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics (Cambridge University Press, 1998).
- 66.R. Sugden, The Economics of Rights, Co-operation and Welfare (Basil Blackwell, 1986).
Associated Data
This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.
Supplementary Materials
Data Availability Statement
There are no data underlying this work.