Skip to main content
PLOS ONE logoLink to PLOS ONE
. 2023 Jan 20;18(1):e0278468. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0278468

Introducing spatial availability, a singly-constrained measure of competitive accessibility

Anastasia Soukhov 1,*, Antonio Páez 1, Christopher D Higgins 2, Moataz Mohamed 3
Editor: Jun Yang4
PMCID: PMC9858359  PMID: 36662779

Abstract

Accessibility indicators are widely used in transportation, urban and healthcare planning, among many other applications. These measures are weighted sums of reachable opportunities from a given origin, conditional on the cost of movement, and are estimates of the potential for spatial interaction. Over time, various proposals have been forwarded to improve their interpretability: one of those methodological additions have been the introduction of competition. In this paper we focus on competition, but first demonstrate how a widely used measure of accessibility with congestion fails to properly match the opportunity-seeking population. We then propose an alternative formulation of accessibility with competition, a measure we call spatial availability. This measure relies on proportional allocation balancing factors (friction of distance and population competition) that are equivalent to imposing a single constraint on conventional gravity-based accessibility. In other words, the proportional allocation of opportunities results in a spatially available opportunities value which is assigned to each origin that, when all origin values are summed, equals the total number of opportunities in the region. We also demonstrate how Two-Stage Floating Catchment Area (2SFCA) methods are equivalent to spatial availability and can be reconceptualized as singly-constrained accessibility. To illustrate the application of spatial availability and compare it to other relevant measures, we use data from the 2016 Transportation Tomorrow Survey of the Greater Golden Horseshoe area in southern Ontario, Canada. Spatial availability is an important contribution since it clarifies the interpretation of accessibility with competition and paves the way for future applications in equity analysis (e.g., spatial mismatch, opportunity benchmarking, policy intervention scenario analysis).

Introduction

The concept of accessibility in transportation studies derives its appeal from the combination of the spatial distribution of opportunities and the cost of reaching them [1, 2]. Accessibility analysis is employed in geography [3, 4], public health [59], real estate valuation [10], tourism [11], and transportation [12, 13] among other areas, with the number of applications growing [14], especially as mobility-based planning is de-emphasized in favor of access-oriented planning [1518].

Accessibility analysis stems from the foundational works of Harris (1954) [19] and Hansen (1959) [1]. From these seminal efforts, many accessibility measures have been derived, particularly after the influential work of Wilson (1971) [20] on spatial interaction (nb., utility-based measures derive from a very different theoretical framework, random utility maximization). Of these, gravity-type accessibility is arguably the most common; since its introduction in the literature, it has been widely adopted in numerous forms [13, 2125]. Hansen-type accessibility indicators are essentially weighted sums of opportunities, with the weights given by an impedance function that depends on the cost of movement and thus measures the intensity of the possibility of interaction [1]. This type of accessibility analysis offers a powerful tool to study the intersection between urban structure and transportation infrastructure [2].

Despite their usefulness, the interpretability of Hansen-type accessibility measures can be challenging [13, 26]. Since they aggregate opportunities, the results are sensitive to the size of the region of interest (e.g., a large city has more jobs than a smaller city). As a consequence, raw outputs are not necessarily comparable across study areas [27]. This limitation becomes evident when surveying studies that implement this type of analysis. For example, studies [5] (in Montréal) and [28] (in Nairobi) report accessibility as the number of health care facilities that can potentially be reached from origins. But what does it mean for a zone to have accessibility to less than 100 facilities in each of these two cities, with their different populations and number of facilities? For that matter, what does it mean for a zone to have accessibility to more than 700 facilities in Montréal, besides being “accessibility rich”? As another example, studies [29] (in Bogota), [30] (in Montréal), and [31] (in Beijing) report accessibility as numbers of jobs, with accessibility values often in the hundreds of thousands, and even exceeding one million jobs for some zones in Beijing and Montréal. As indicators of urban structure, these measures are informative, but the meaning of one million accessible jobs is harder to pin down: how many jobs must any single person have access to? Clearly, the answer to this question depends on how many people demand jobs.

The interpretability of Hansen-type accessibility has been discussed in numerous studies, including recently by [32, 33], and in greater depth by [34]. As hinted above, the limitations in interpretability are frequently caused by ignoring competition; without competition, each opportunity is assumed to be equally available to every single opportunity-seeking individual that can reach it [33, 35, 36]. This assumption is appropriate when the opportunity of interest is non-exclusive, that is, if use by one unit of population does not preclude use by another. For instance, national parks with abundant space are seldom used to full capacity, so the presence of some population does not exclude use by others. When it comes to exclusive opportunities, or when operations may be affected by congestion, the solution has been to account for competition. Several efforts exist that do so. In our reckoning, the first such approach was proposed by Weibull (1976) [37], whereby the distance decay of the supply of employment and the demand for employment (by workers) were formulated under so-called axiomatic assumptions. This approach was then applied by Joseph (1984) [38] in the context of healthcare, to quantify the availability of general practitioners in Canada. About two decades later, Shen (1998) [35] independently re-discovered Weibull’s [37] formula [see footnote (7) in Shen (1998) 35] and deconstructed it to consider accessibility for different modes. These advances were subsequently popularized as the family of Two-Stage Floating Catchment area (2SFCA) methods [39] that have found widespread adoption in healthcare, education, and food systems [4044].

An important development contained in Shen (1998)‘s work is a proof that the population-weighted sum of the accessibility measure with competition equates to the number of opportunities available [footnote (7) and Appendix A in 35]. This demonstration gives the impression that Shen-type accessibility allocates all opportunities to the origins, however to our knowledge, it has not been interpreted by literature in this way. For instance, [34, 45, 46] all use Shen-type accessibility to calculate job access but report values as ‘competitive accessibility scores’ or simply ‘job accessibility’. These works do not explicitly recognize that jobs that are assigned to each origin are in fact a proportion of all the opportunities in the system. This recognition, we argue, is critical to interpreting the meaning of the final result. Thus, in this paper we intend to revisit accessibility with competition within the context of disentangling how opportunities are allocated. We first argue that Shen (1998)‘s competitive accessibility (’Shen-type accessibility’ in this paper) misleadingly refers to the total zonal population to equal the travel-cost discounted opportunity-seeking population. This equivocation, we believe, results in an ambiguous interpretation of what Shen-type accessibility represents as the allocation of opportunities to population is masked by the results presenting as rates (i.e., opportunities per capita). We then propose an alternative formulation of accessibility that incorporates competition by adopting a proportional allocation mechanism; we name this measure spatial availability. The use of balancing factors for proportional allocation is akin to imposing a single constraint on the accessibility indicator, in the spirit of Wilson (1971)’s [20] spatial interaction model.

The key motivations of this paper are as follows:

  • To address and improve on the interpretability of Hansen-type accessibility measure; and

  • To consider competition from the perspective of the population for opportunities within an accessibility measure.

In this way, the paper’s aim is three-fold:

  • First, we aim to demonstrate that Shen-type (and hence Weibull (1976) [37] accessibility and the popular 2SFCA method) produce equivocal estimates of opportunities allocated as the result is presented as a rate (i.e., opportunities per capita);

  • Second, we introduce a new measure, spatial availability, which we submit is a more interpretable alternative to Shen-type accessibility, since opportunities in the system are preserved and proportionally allocated to the population; and

  • Third, we show how Shen-type accessibility (and 2SFCA methods) can be seen as measures of singly-constrained accessibility.

Discussion is supported by the use of the small synthetic example of Shen (1998) [35] and empirical data drawn from the 2016 Transportation Tomorrow Survey of the Greater Toronto and Hamilton Area in Ontario, Canada. In the spirit of openness of research in the spatial sciences [4749] this paper has a companion open data product [50]. All code is available for replicability and reproducibility purposes at the cited GitHub repository [51].

Accessibility measures revisited

In this section we revisit Hansen-type and Shen-type accessibility indicators. We adopt the convention of using a capital letter for absolute values (number of opportunities) and lower case for rates (opportunities per capita).

Hansen-type accessibility

Hansen-type accessibility measures follow the general formulation shown in Eq (1):

Si=j=1JOj·f(cij) (1)

where:

  • cij is a measure of the cost of moving between i and j.

  • f(⋅) is an impedance function of cij; it can take the form of any monotonically decreasing function chosen based on positive or normative criteria [52].

  • i is a set of origin locations (i = 1, ⋯, N).

  • j is a set of destination locations (j = 1, ⋯, J).

  • Oj is the number of opportunities at location j; O=j=1JOj is the total supply of opportunities in the study region.

  • S is Hansen-type accessibility as weighted sum of opportunities.

As formally defined, accessibility Si is the sum of opportunities that can be reached from location i, weighted down by an impedance function of the cost of travel cij. Summing the opportunities in the neighborhood of i provides estimates of the number of opportunities that can potentially be reached from i. Several measures result from using a variety of impedance functions; for example, cumulative opportunities measures are obtained when f(⋅) is a binary or indicator function [13, e.g., 30, 53, 54]. Other measures use impedance functions modeled after any monotonically decreasing function [e.g., Gaussian, inverse power, negative exponential, or log-normal, among others, see, inter alia, 55–58]. In practice, accessibility measures with different impedance functions tend to be highly correlated [55, 59, 60].

Gravity-based accessibility has been shown to be an excellent indicator of the intersection between spatially distributed opportunities and transportation infrastructure [14, 55, 57]. However, beyond enabling comparisons of relative values, they are not highly interpretable on their own [26]. To address the issue of interpretability, previous research has aimed to index and normalize values on a per demand-population basis [6163]. However, as recent research on accessibility discusses [27, 33, 34, 36], these steps do not adequately consider competition. In effect, when calculating Si, every opportunity enters the weighted sum once for every origin i that can reach it. This makes interpretability opaque, and to complicate matters, can also bias the estimated landscape of opportunity.

Shen-type competitive accessibility

To account for competition, the influential works of Shen (1998) [35] and Weibull (1976) [37], as well as the widely used 2SFCA approach of Luo & Wang (2003) [39], adjust Hansen-type accessibility to account for the population’s demand for opportunities in the region of interest. The mechanics of this approach consist of calculating, for every destination j, the population that can reach the opportunity(ies) given the impedance function f(⋅); let us call this the effective opportunity-seeking population (Eq (2)). This value can be seen as the Hansen-type market area (accessibility to population) of j. The opportunities at j are divided by the sum of the effective opportunity-seeking population to obtain a measure of opportunities per capita, i.e., Rj in Eq (3). This can be thought of as the level of service at j. Per capita values are then allocated back to the population at i, again subject to the impedance function as seen in Eq (4); this is accessibility with competition.

Pij*=Pi·f(cij) (2)
Rj=OjiPij* (3)
ai=jRj·f(cij) (4)

where:

  • a is Shen-type accessibility as weighted sum of opportunities per capita (or weighted level of service).

  • cij is a measure of the cost of moving between i and j.

  • f(⋅) is an impedance function of cij.

  • i is a set of origin locations (i = 1, ⋯, N).

  • j is a set of destination locations (j = 1, ⋯, J).

  • Oj is the number of opportunities at location j; O=j=1JOj is the total supply of opportunities in the study region.

  • Pi is the population at location i.

  • Pij* is the population at location i that can reach destination j according to the impedance function; we call this the effective opportunity-seeking population.

  • Rj is the ratio of opportunities at j to the sum over all origins of the effective opportunity-seeking population that can reach j; in other words, this is the total number of opportunities per capita found at j.

Shen describes Pi as the “the number of people in location i seeking opportunities” [35]. In our view, this is somewhat equivocal and where misinterpretation of the final results may arise. Consider a population center where the population is only willing to take an opportunity if the trip required is less than or equal to 60 minutes. This travel behaviour is captured by the following impedance function:

f(cij)={1ifcij60min0otherwise (5)

If an employment center is less than 60 minutes away, the population can seek opportunities there (i.e., f(cij) = 1). But are these people still part of the opportunity-seeking population for jobs located two hours away? How about four hours away? We assume that they are not part of the opportunity-seeking population because their travel behaviour, as represented by the impedance function, would yield f(cij) = 0, eliminating them from the effective opportunity-seeking population Pij*. We see Shen’s definition as ambiguous because, for the purpose of calculating accessibility, the impedance function defines what constitutes the population that effectively can seek opportunities at remote locations. Thus, Pi should be plainly understood as the population at location i (as defined above) and not the “the number of people in location i seeking opportunities”. In other words, Pi and Pij* are confounded.

Furthermore, an identical misunderstanding can be described for Oj which is defined as “the number of relevant opportunities in location j” in [35] (our emphasis). Oj is adjusted by the same f(cij) in Eq (4), so the relevancy is determined by the travel behaviour associated with the impedance function and not only by Oj. For this reason, Oj should be understood plainly as the opportunities at location j (as defined above).

Misunderstanding Pi and Oj may lead to a misleading interpretation of the final result ai, especially as expressed in Shen’s proof (see Eq (6)).

i=1NaiPi=j=1JOj (6)

Confounding Pi with the effective opportunity-seeking population and confounding Oj with the jobs taken may cause us to misunderstand ai as “relevant opportunities” per “people in location i seeking opportunities”. Instead, as mathematically expressed in Shen’s proof, ai is a proportion of the opportunities available to the population, since multiplying ai by the population at i and summing for all origins in the system equals to the total number of opportunities in the system. Embedded in ai is already the travel behaviour, so Pi and Oj must be plainly understand as the population at i and opportunities at j for Eq (6) to hold true.

Shen’s synthetic example

In this section we use the synthetic example in Shen (1998) [35] to highlight the importance of understanding Pi and Oj as simply the population at the origin i and the opportunities at destination j, respectively. This is critical to understanding how opportunities are allocated to the population based on the impedance function.

Table 1 contains the information needed to calculate Si and ai for this example. We use a negative exponential impedance function with β = 0.1 as also used in Shen (1998) [35, see footnote (5)]:

f(cij)=exp(-β·cij)

Table 1. Summary description of the synthetic example: Hansen-type accessibility Si, Shen-type accessibility ai, and spatial availability Vi with beta = 0.1 (light yellow) and beta = 0.6 (light grey).

Origin A B C
Dest. 1 2 3 1 2 3 1 2 3
Pop. 50000 50000 50000 150000 150000 150000 10000 10000 10000
Jobs 100000 100000 10000 100000 100000 10000 100000 100000 10000
TT 15 30 100 30 15 100 100 100 15
f(TT) 0.223 0.050 < 0.001 0.050 0.223 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.223
Pop * f(TT) 11156.5 2489.4 2.3 7468.1 33469.5 6.8 0.5 0.5 2231.3
Jobs * f(TT) 22313.0 4978.7 0.5 4978.7 22313.0 0.5 4.5 4.5 2231.3
S_i 27292.2 27292.2 27292.2 27292.2 27292.2 27292.2 2240.4 2240.4 2240.4
a_i 1.337 1.337 1.337 0.888 0.888 0.888 0.996 0.996 0.996
f(TT) < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001
Pop * f(TT) 6.170 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.002 18.511 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 1.234
Jobs * f(TT) 12.341 0.002 < 0.001 0.002 12.341 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 1.234
S_i 12.343 12.343 12.343 12.343 12.343 12.343 1.234 1.234 1.234
a_i 1.999 1.999 1.999 0.667 0.667 0.667 1.000 1.000 1.000
F⌃c 0.238 0.238 0.238 0.714 0.714 0.714 0.048 0.048 0.048
F⌃p 0.817 0.182 < 0.001 0.182 0.817 < 0.001 < 0.001 < 0.001 1.000
F 0.599 0.069 0.001 0.401 0.931 0.003 < 0.001 < 0.001 0.996
V_ij 59900.6 6922.7 10.1 40096.9 93076.0 30.4 2.4 1.3 9959.5
V_i 66833.5 66833.5 66833.5 133203.4 133203.4 133203.4 9963.2 9963.2 9963.2

In Table 1, we see that population centers A and B have equal Hansen-type accessibility (SA = SB = 27,292 jobs). On the other hand, the isolated satellite town of C has low accessibility (SC = 2,240 jobs). But center B, despite its high accessibility, is a large population center. C, in contrast, is smaller but also relatively isolated and has a balanced ratio of jobs (10,0000 jobs) to population (10,000 people). It is difficult from these outputs to determine whether accessibility at C is better or worse than that at A or B.

The results are easier to interpret when we consider Shen-type accessibility. The results indicate that aA≈ 1.337 jobs per capita, aB≈ 0.888, and aC≈ 0.996. The latter value is sensible given the jobs-population balance of C. Center A is relatively close to a large number of jobs (more jobs than the population of A). The opposite is true of B. According to Shen (1998) [35], the sum of the population-weighted accessibility ai is exactly equal to the number of jobs in the region following Shen’s proof:

i=1NaiPi=j=1JOj50,000×1.3366693+150,000×0.8880224+10,000×0.9963171=210,000

As mentioned earlier, this property under Shen’s definition of Pi“people in location i seeking opportunities”, gives the impression that all jobs sought are allocated to the people located at each origin i. In other words, Shen defines Pi to mean Pij* (i.e., the effective opportunity-seeking population that is already adjusted by travel behaviour) instead of defining it to simply be the full population at i (i.e., Pi). As seen in column Pop * f(TT) in Table 1 (i.e., Pij*=Pi·f(cij)), the number of individuals from population center A that are willing to reach employment centers 1, 2, and 3 are 11,156, 2,489, and 2.27 respectively. Therefore, the total effective opportunity-seeking population at A is PA*=jPAj*, that is, 13,647.27 people: this is considerably lower than the total population of A (i.e., PA = 50,000 people). Demonstrated as follows, using Pij* in the calculations associated with this proof results in only 56,834.59 jobs being allocated to the population, instead of the nominal number of jobs in the region that is over three times this number (i.e., 210,000 jobs).

i=1NaiPij*=(11,156.51+2,489.35+2.26)×1.3366693+(7,468.06+33,469.52+6.81)×0.8880224+(4.54+4.54+2,231.20)×0.996317156,834.59

Furthermore, even when Shen’s Pi is understood plainly as the total population at i, the meaning of the proof may still be ambiguous. The proof can still give the impression that all jobs are allocated to the total population, since total population (i=1NPi) goes into the equation and total jobs (j=1JOj) in the region is the result. However, this impression is incomplete as it does not reflect the magnitude of population that takes jobs and the number of people being considered for jobs: these magnitudes are a product of the impedance function. The magnitudes are not obvious because the result, ai, is a rate (i.e., opportunities per capita).

Let us consider a modification to the travel behaviour of the example discussed to illustrate how the presentation of ai as a rate obscures the magnitude of the effective opportunity-seeking population. We modify the example by increasing the β to 0.6 (compared to the previous value of 0.1; see Fig 1). This modification increases the cost of travel and thus the impedance function (an expression of the population’s relative willingness to travel to opportunities). The modification reflects a population that is relatively less willing to travel to opportunities further away compared to the previous β value. The Hansen-type and Shen-type values are presented in the yellow rows of Table 1.

Fig 1. Comparison of two negative exponential impedance functions used in the synthetic example.

Fig 1

The x-axis represents the travel time (in mins) and the y-axis represents the impedance function at each travel time.

As expected, Hansen-type accessibility drops quite dramatically after this β modification: the friction of distance is so high that few opportunities are within reach. In contrast, Shen-type accessibility converges to the jobs:population ratio (i.e., origin A is 100,00050,000=2). This is explained by the way the impedance function excludes the population in droves, thus reducing the competition for jobs: as seen in Table 1, the effective opportunity-seeking population from A is only about equal to 6.17. Likewise, the number of jobs at 1 weighted by the impedance is only 12.341. In other words, competition is low (limited onto the the population close to job centers) because jobs are expensive to reach, but those willing to reach jobs enjoy relatively high accessibility (in the limit, the jobs:population ratio). On the other hand, the accessibility is effectively zero for those in the population prevented by the impedance from reaching any jobs (the population not near the job centers).

In what follows, we propose an alternative derivation of Shen (1998) [35] accessibility with competition that explicitly clarifies the opportunities allocated to the effective opportunity-seeking population within its formulation. Hence, the results are not only more interpretable, but also extend the potential of accessibility analysis.

Introducing spatial availability: A singly-constrained measure of accessibility

In brief, we define the spatial availability at i (Vi) as the proportion of all opportunities O that are allocated to i from all destinations j:

Vi=j=1NOjFijt

where:

  • Fijt is a balancing factor that depends on the population and cost of movement in the system.

  • Oj is the number of opportunities at j.

  • Vi is the number of spatially available opportunities from the perspective of i.

The general form of spatial availability is also as a sum, and the fundamental difference between Hansen- and Shen-type accessibility is that opportunities are allocated proportionally. Balancing factor Fijt consists of two components: a population-based balancing factor Fip and an impedance-based balancing factor Fijc that, respectively, allocate opportunities to i in proportion to the size of the population of the different competing centers (the mass effect of the gravity model) and the cost of reaching opportunities (the impedance effect). In the next two subsections, we explain the intuition behind the method before defining it in full.

Proportional allocation by population

According to the gravity modelling framework, the potential for interaction depends on the mass (i.e., the population) and the friction of distance (i.e., the impedance function). We begin by describing the proposed proportional allocation mechanism based on demand by the population. Recall, the total population in the example is 210,000. The proportion of the population by population center is:

FAp=50,000210,000FBp=150,000210,000FCp=10,000210,000

Jobs are allocated proportionally from each employment center to each population center depending on their population sizes as per the balancing factors Fip. In this way, employment center 1 allocates 100,000·50,000210,000=23,809.52 jobs to A; 100,000·150,000210,000=71,428.57 jobs to B; and 100,000·10,000210,000=7,142.857 jobs to C. Notice how this mechanism ensures that the total number of jobs at employment center 1 is preserved at 100,000.

We can verify that the number of jobs allocated is consistent with the total number of jobs in the system:

Employmentcenter1topopulationcentersA,B,andC:100,000·50,000210,000+100,000·150,000210,000+100,000·10,000210,000=100,000Employmentcenter2topopulationcentersA,B,andC:100,000·50,000210,000+100,000·150,000210,000+100,000·10,000210,000=100,000Employmentcenter3topopulationcentersA,B,andC:10,000·50,000210,000+10,000·150,000210,000+10,000·10,000210,000=10,000

In the general case where there are N population centers in the region, we define the following population-based balancing factors in Eq (7):

Fip=Piαi=1NPiα (7)

Balancing factor Fip corresponds to the proportion of the population in origin i relative to the population in the region. On the right hand side of the equation, the numerator Piα is the population at origin i. The summation in the denominator is over i = 1, ⋯, N, and adds up to the total population of the region. Notice that we incorporate an empirical parameter α. The role of α is to modulate the effect of demand by population. When α < 1, opportunities are allocated more rapidly to smaller centers relative to larger ones; α > 1 achieves the opposite effect.

Balancing factor Fip can now be used to proportionally allocate a share of available jobs at j to origin i. The number of jobs available to i from j balanced by population shares is defined as follows:

Vijp=OjFipi=1NFip

In the general case where there are J employment centers, the total number of jobs available from all destinations to i is simply the sum of Vijp over j = 1, ⋯, J:

Vip=j=1JOjFipi=1NFip

Since the factor Fip, when summed over i = 1, ⋯, N always equals to 1 (i.e., i=1NFip=1), the sum of all spatially available jobs equals O, the total number of opportunities in the region:

i=1NVip=i=1Nj=1JOjFipi=1NFip=i=1NFipi=1NFip·j=1JOj=j=1JOj=O

The terms Fip act here as the balancing factors of the gravity model when a single constraint is imposed (i.e., to ensure that the sums of columns are equal to the number of opportunities per destination, see Ortúzar & Willumsen (2011) [64], pp. 179–180 and pp. 183–184). As a result, the sum of spatial availability for all population centers equals the total number of opportunities.

The discussion so far concerns only the mass effect (i.e., population size) of the gravity model. In addition, the potential for interaction is thought to decrease with increasing cost, so next we define similar balancing factors but based on the impedance.

Proportional allocation by cost

Clearly, using only balancing factor Fip to calculate spatial availability Vip does not account for the cost of reaching employment centers. Consider instead a set of balancing factors Fijc that account for the friction of distance for our example. Recall that the impedance function f(cij) equals exp(−βcij) where β = 0.1 and travel time cij is either 15, 30 or 60 minutes. For instance, the impedance-based balancing factors Fijc would be the following for employment center 1 (employment center 2 and 3 have their own balancing factor values for each origin i as will be discussed later):

FA1c=0.2231300.223130+0.049787+0.000045=0.8174398FB1c=0.0497870.223130+0.049787+0.000045=0.1823954FC1c=0.0000450.223130+0.049787+0.000045=0.0001648581

Balancing factors Fijc use the impedance function to proportionally allocate more jobs to closer population centers, that is, to those with populations more willing to reach the jobs. Indeed, the factors Fijc can be thought of as the proportion of the population at i willing to travel to destination j, conditional on the travel behavior as given by the impedance function. For instance, 81.74398% of jobs from employment center 1 are allocated to population center A based on impedance.

So as follows from our example, of the 100,000 jobs at employment center 1 the number of jobs allocated to population center A is 100, 000 × 0.8174398 = 81, 743.98 jobs; the number allocated to population center B is 100, 000 × 0.1823954 = 18, 239.54 jobs; and the number allocated to population center C is 100, 000 × 0.0001648581 = 16.48581 jobs. We see once more that the total number of jobs at the employment center is preserved at 100,000. In this example, the proportional allocation mechanism assigns the largest share of jobs to population center A, which is the closest to employment center 1 and the smallest to the more distant population center C.

In the general case where there are N population centers and J employment centers in the region, we define the following impedance-based balancing factors:

Fijc=f(cij)i=1Nf(cij) (8)

The total number of jobs available to i from j according to impedance is defined as follows:

Vijc=OjFijci=1NFijc

The total number of jobs available to i from all destinations is:

Vic=j=1JOjFijci=1NFijc

Like the population-based allocation factors, Fic summed over i = 1, ⋯, N always equals to 1 (i.e., i=1NFijc=1). As before, the sum of all spatially available jobs equals O, the total number of opportunities in the region:

i=1NVic=i=1Nj=1JOjFijci=1NFijc=i=1NFijci=1NFijc·j=1JOj=j=1JOj=O

We are now ready to more formally define spatial availability with due consideration to both population and travel cost effects.

Assembling mass and impedance effects

Population and the cost of travel are both part of the gravity modelling framework. Since the balancing factors defined in the preceding sections are proportions, they can be combined multiplicatively to obtain their joint effect. This multiplicative relationship can alternatively be understood as the joint probability of allocating opportunities and is captured by Eq (9), where Fip is the population-based balancing factor that grants a larger share of the existing opportunities to larger centers and Fijc is the impedance-based balancing factor that grants a larger share of the existing opportunities to closer centers. This is in line with the tradition of gravity modeling.

Fijt=Fip·Fijci=1NFip·Fijc (9)

with Fip and Fijc as defined in Eqs (7) and (8) respectively. The combined balancing factor Fijt is used to proportionally allocate jobs from j to i. Hence, spatial availability is given by Eq (10).

Vi=j=1JOjFijt (10)

The terms in Eq (10):

  • Fijt is a balancing factor as defined in Eq (9).

  • i is a set of origin locations in the region i = 1, ⋯, N.

  • j is a set of destination locations in the region j = 1, ⋯, J.

  • Oj is the number of opportunities at location j.

  • Vi is the spatial availability at i.

Notice that, unlike Si in Hansen-type accessibility (Eq (1)), the population enters the calculation of Vi through Fip. Returning to the example in Fig 2, Table 1 also contains the information needed to calculate Vi, with β set again to 0.1. Column V_ij are the jobs available to each origin from each employment center. In this column VA1 = 59,901 is the number of jobs available at A from employment center 1. Column V_i (i.e., j=1JVij) gives the total number of jobs available to origin i. We can verify that the total number of jobs available is consistent with the total number of jobs in the region (with some small rounding error):

i=1NVi=66,833+133,203+9,963210,000

Fig 2. Shen (1998) synthetic example with locations of employment centers (in orange), population centers (in blue), number of jobs and population and travel times.

Fig 2

Compared the calculated values of Vi to column S_i (Hansen-type accessibility) in Table 1. The spatial availability values are more intuitive. Recall that population centers A and B had identical Hansen-type accessibility to employment opportunities. According to Vi, population center A has greater job availability due to: 1) its close proximity to employment center 1; combined with 2) less competition (i.e., a majority of the population have to travel longer distances to reach employment center 1). Job availability is lower for population center B due to much higher competition (150,000 people can reach 100,000 jobs at equal cost). And center C has almost as many jobs available as it has population.

As discussed above, Hansen-type accessibility is not designed to preserve the number of jobs in the region. Shen-type accessibility ends up preserving the number of jobs in the region but the definitions of variables are internally obscured; the only way it preserves the number of jobs is if the effect of the impedance function is ignored when expanding the values of jobs per capita to obtain the total number of opportunities. The proportional allocation procedure described above, in contrast, consistently returns a number of jobs available that matches the total number of jobs in the region.

Since the jobs spatially available are consistent with the jobs in the region, it is possible to define a measure of spatial availability per capita as presented in Eq (11):

vi=ViPi (11)

And, since the jobs are preserved, it is possible to use the regional jobs per capita (j=1JOji=1NPi) as a benchmark to compare the spatial availability of jobs per capita at each origin.

In the example, since the population is equal to the number of jobs, the regional value of jobs per capita is 1.0. To complete the illustrative example, the spatial availability of jobs per capita by origin is:

v1=V1P1=66,833.4750,000=1.337v2=V2P2=133,203.4150,000=0.888v3=V3P3=9,963.17110,000=0.996 (12)

We can see that population center A has fewer jobs per capita than the regional benchmark, center B has more, and center C is at parity. Remarkably, the spatial availability per capita matches the values of ai in Table 1. S1 Appendix has a proof of the mathematical equivalence between the two measures. It is interesting to notice how Weibull (1976) [37] and Shen (1998) [35], as well as this paper, all reach identical expressions starting from different assumptions; this effect is known as equifinality (see Ortúzar & Willumsen (2011) [64], p. 333 and Williams (1981) [65]). This result means that Shen-type accessibility and 2SFCA can be re-conceptualized as singly-constrained accessibility measures along with the proposed spatial availability measure.

Why does proportional allocation matter?

We have shown that Shen-type accessibility and spatial availability produce equifinal results when accessibility per-capita is computed. At this point it is reasonable to ask whether the distinction between these two measures is of any importance.

Conceptually, we would argue that the confounded populations in Shen-type accessibility leads to internal inconsistency in the calculation of total opportunities in Shen (1998) [35]: this points to a deeper issue that is only evident when we consider the intermediate values of the method. To illustrate, Table 1 shows results of ai that are reasonable (and they match exactly the spatial availability per capita). But when we dig deeper, these results mask potentially misleading values for the jobs allocated and the number of jobs taken. For instance, a region with a high jobs:population ratio but a prohibitive transportation network that results in a high cost of travel may yield a high ai value. This value, however, can conceal a low effective opportunity-seeking population and a proportionally low number of allocated jobs, while also obscuring the magnitude of the population that does and does not take jobs.

In addition, the intermediate accessibility values of ai (Shen-type measure) may also lead to impact estimates that are deceptive [66]. For example, the estimated region-wide cost of travel considering the jobs allocated by ai in Table 1 (i.e., Jobs*f(TT)) is as follows:

22,313×15min+4,979×30min+0.454×100min+4,979×30min+22,313×15min+0.454×100min+4.54×100min+4.54×100min+2,231×15min=1,002,594min

In contrast, the estimated region-wide cost of travel according to Vi in Table 1 is as follows:

59,901×15min+6,923×30min+10×100min+40,097×30min+93,076×15min+30×100min+2.4×100min+1.3×100min+9,959×15min=3,859,054min

Often referred to as ‘the supply of jobs’ (or simply Hansen-type accessibility) in the Shen-type measure: Jobs*f(TT) cannot be used to understand the region-wide cost of travel. Recall how we define Pop*f(TT) as the effective opportunity-seeking population (Pij*), Jobs*f(TT) similarly represents the effective opportunities allocated and sums to approximately 56,824 out of a total of 210,000 jobs. Like Pop*f(TT), the effective opportunities allocated to each origin is only a reflection of the impedance function and not the actual number of opportunities allocated to each origin. Therefore, the resulting 1, 002, 594 min is not a meaningful measure of the cost of travel in the system.

However, since spatial availability allocates the actual number of opportunities to each origin; the 3,859,054 min can be used to quantify the system-wide impacts of competitive accessibility in this region. We know spatial availability’s output is the number of opportunities at each i since the combined balancing factors allocate a proportional amount of the total opportunities to each i such that the number of opportunities allocated to each i sum to equal the total opportunities in the region.

Empirical example of Toronto

In this section we illustrate the application of spatial availability through an empirical example. We use full-time employment origin-destination flows from the city of Toronto. Toronto is within the Greater Golden Horseshoe (GGH) (31,500 km2), the most densely populated and industrialized region in Canada. Within the GGH is the Greater Toronto and Hamilton (GTHA); it forms the most populous metropolitan regions in Canada and the core urban agglomeration in the GGH.

The GTHA contains the city of Toronto, the most populous city in Canada, and the focus of this empirical example; it is used to demonstrate the application of the proposed spatial availability measure along with how it compares to Hansen- and Shen-type measures. We explain the data and then detail the calculated comparisons.

GGH data

We obtained full-time employment flows from the 2016 Transportation Tomorrow Survey (TTS). This household travel survey collects representative travel journey information from all 20 municipalities contained within the GGH area (Fig 3) every five years [67]. The data set includes origin to destination flows associated with full-time employed people at the level of Traffic Analysis Zones (TAZ) (3,764 TAZ in the GGH) i.e., the number of full-time workers at origin household TAZ (3,446,957 workers in the GGH) and their matching employment destination TAZ (3,081,900 associated jobs in the GGH). TAZ are a unit of spatial analysis that are defined as part of the TTS. More broadly, TAZ are commonly used to ascribe production and attraction of trips in the context of transportation planning modelling. In the GGH data set, TAZ contain on average 916 workers and 819 jobs (descriptive statistics in Fig 3). The TTS data is based on a representative sample of between 3% to 5% of households in the GGH and is weighted to reflect the population covering the study area as a whole [67].

Fig 3. TTS 2016 study area (GGH, Ontario, Canada) along with the descriptive statistics of the origin destination (OD) pairs (count of workers that travel to their place of employment) by origin TAZ, calculated OD car travel time (TT), workers per TAZ, and jobs per TAZ.

Fig 3

Contains 20 municipalities/regions (black boundaries) and sub-regions (dark gray boundaries).

To generate the travel cost for the full-time employment trips, travel times between origins and destinations (i.e., centroids of the TAZ) are calculated for car travel using the R package {r5r} with a street network retrieved from OpenStreetMap [68, 69]. For inter-TAZ trips, a 3 hr travel time threshold is selected as it captures 99% of population-employment pairs (travel times summarized in Fig 3). This method does not account for traffic congestion or modal split, which can be approximated through additional methods [70, 71]. For simplicity, we carry on with the assumption that all trips are taken by car in uncongested travel conditions. Additionally, we assume all intra-TAZ trips are equal to 0.1 minutes for illustrative purposes. All data and data preparation steps are documented and can be freely explored in the companion open data product {TTS2016R}.

Spatial employment characteristics in Toronto

As mentioned, the focus of this empirical example is on the city of Toronto. It is the largest city in the GGH and represents a significant subset of workers and jobs in the GGH; 22% of workers in the GGH live in Toronto and 25% of jobs that these workers take are located within Toronto. The spatial distribution of jobs and workers is shown in Fig 4. A high density of jobs can be found in the central southern part of Toronto (the downtown core). Spatial trends in the distribution of workers is more uniform relative to the distribution of jobs.

Fig 4. Spatial distribution of full-time jobs (top) and full-time working population (bottom) at each TAZ for Toronto as provided by the 2016 TTS.

Fig 4

Black lines represent expressways and black dashed lines represent subway lines. All white TAZ have no worker population or jobs.

Next, the spatial distribution of the estimated car travel time (green) and the associated standard deviation (grey) is visualized in Fig 5. Overall, it can be seen that car travel time is lower within the downtown core and higher outside of the downtown core. Trends from both plots indicate that trips originating from within the center of Toronto are shorter and more similar in length than trips originating from closer to the Toronto boundaries.

Fig 5. Mean car travel time to jobs per origin (top) and standard deviation of car travel times per origin (bottom) for the city of Toronto.

Fig 5

Origin destination flows are provided by the 2016 TTS and car travel times estimated using r5r. Black lines represent expressways and black dashed lines represent subway lines. White TAZ represent a TAZ with no workers hence no travel time.

Calibration of an impedance function for Toronto

In the synthetic example introduced in Section 2, we use a negative exponential function with the parameter reported by Shen (1998) [35]. For the empirical Toronto data set, we calibrate an impedance function on the trip length distribution (TLD) of commute trips. Briefly, a TLD represents the proportion of trips that are taken at a specific travel cost (e.g., travel time); this distribution is commonly used to derive impedance functions in accessibility research [7274].

As mentioned, the calculations are undertaken for the city of Toronto using only the full-time employed population in the city and associated jobs in Toronto. Specifically, edge trips are not included, such as trips originating in Toronto but finishing outside of Toronto (i.e., jobs not in Toronto) and trips originating outside of Toronto but finishing in Toronto (i.e., full-time employed people living outside of Toronto). The empirical and theoretical TLD for this Toronto data set are represented in the top-left panel of Fig 6. Maximum likelihood estimation and the Nelder-Mead method for direct optimization available within the {fitdistrplus} package [75] is used. Based on goodness-of-fit criteria and associated diagnostics, the normal distribution is selected (see Fig 6).

Fig 6. Car trip length distribution and calibrated normal distribution impedance function (red line) with associated Q-Q and P-P plots.

Fig 6

Based on the estimated car travel times for full-time employment OD trips in Toronto from the TTS 2016.

For reference, the normal distribution is defined in Eq (13). It depends on a mean parameter μ (estimated to be 14.169) and a standard deviation parameter σ (estimated to be 7.369).

f(x)=1σ2πe-12(x-μσ)2 (13)

Together, Figs 4 and 5 and the calibrated impedance function demonstrate the spatial distribution of worker and job data in Toronto and the inputs for this study’s calculation of spatial availability, Shen- and Hansen- type measures.

Accessibility and spatial availability of jobs in Toronto

Absolute opportunity values

Fig 7 contains the number of jobs accessible using Shen-type accessibility, Hansen-type accessibility, and the number of jobs available using the spatial availability measure. The values from all measures are represented on the same axis as they measure the absolute value of jobs accessible to the workers at the origin. In the top plot, the Shen-type accessibility is multiplied by the effective opportunity-seeking population to yield a value that corresponds to absolute number of accessible jobs (considering competition) according to Shen’s definition. In the middle plot, the Hansen-type accessibility is an unconstrained case of accessibility where all jobs that are in-reach of each origin (according to the impedance function). In other words, in this plot, each value corresponds to the number of jobs that can be reach at each origin assuming no competition. Lastly, in the bottom plot, the proposed spatial availability measure is shown. Spatial availability is a constrained case of accessibility that proportionally allocates the number of jobs, at each origin, considering competition from the population in nearby origin and the relative travel cost (according to the impedance function).

Fig 7. Estimated accessibility to jobs (# of jobs) in Toronto according to Shen-type measure multipled by the effective opportunity-seeking population (top), Hansen-type measure (middle), and spatial availability (bottom).

Fig 7

Black lines represent expressways and black dashed lines represent subway lines. All white TAZ have no worker population or jobs, i.e., with null accessibility values. Legend scale is square root transformed to effectively visualize the range of values.

What is notable about the bottom plot is that the proportional allocation mechanism of spatial availability ensures that the job availability value for each origin all sums to the city-wide total of 771,496 jobs (i.e., the number of destination flows from Toronto origins to Toronto destinations). The number of accessible jobs at each origin can therefore be interpreted as the number of available jobs to each origin based on the relative travel behaviour and density of competition for jobs (i.e., worker population). A proportion of each of the 771,496 jobs in Toronto are only allocated once to each origin. In terms of the middle plot, the city-wide total sum of Hansen-type accessibility is 4,370,250 jobs. This value is relatively meaningless since the measure is unconstrained and represents the sum of opportunities that have been counted anywhere from 1 to many times depending on the impedance function. As previously discussed, unconstrained counting of the same opportunity by all origins is not an issue if the opportunity itself is non-exclusive, but since one job can only be given to one worker (especially since the worker and job data is derived from origin destination (OD) flows), it is inappropriate to use unconstrained measures to capture employment characteristics. Comparing the middle and bottom plots, it is evident that the unconstrained counting of opportunities (Hansen-type) results in absolute values that are higher throughout the city, particularly in TAZ that are in proximity to high job density (recall Fig 4). These same trends are not present in the spatial availability bottom plot as the absolute value is lower than Hansen-type accessibility middle plot since the proximity to high job density and competition from worker density is proportionally metered.

Lastly, the top plot visualizes the absolute Shen-type measure (as understood by Shen’s definition of Pi being equal to Pij*) and sums to the city-wide value of 2,125,281 jobs by multiplying ai by the effective opportunity-seeking population Pij* (i.e., the denominator of the rate). This plot demonstrates how confounding Pi with Pij* yields an incorrect number of competitively accessible jobs: this is evidently incorrect because the sum of aiPij* greatly exceeds the city-wide total of workers (i.e., 2,125,281 > 771,496). To the authors’ knowledge, literature has not attempted to convert Shen-type accessibility to the absolute value of accessible jobs in the way demonstrated in the top plot: we suspect this is the case because of the ambiguous definition in the Shen-type measure that conflates Pij* with Pi. If ai is multiplied by Pi, it yields the same value as Vi, but since the definition of Shen-type measure is equivocal, doing so is not clear since the denominator of ai (note: which is a rate) is not Pi. The resulting plot, spatially, is similar to spatial availability (bottom plot) but certain TAZ have exceptionally high values in an inconsistent way. This is because ai uses the impedance function values for both access to jobs (numerator) and the competition from neighboring workers (denominator Pij*) to adjust their impact: using Pij* does not consistently isolate the absolute value of accessible jobs. However, readers should note that if ai is multiplied by Pi it yields the same values at Vi (bottom plot) (the proof for mathematically equivalency is in S1 Appendix). As also mentioned earlier, the formulation of the denominator and numerator of ai is ambiguous. To presume that multiplying it by Pi would disentangle the rate and yield the absolute value of accessible and available (i.e., considering competition) jobs is not clear within Shen-type measure’s definition. However, through the calculation of spatial availability Vi, the absolute value of accessible and available opportunities at a zone i is clear.

Internal values

Carrying on the discussion on how to retrieve the absolute value of available jobs using the Shen-type measure (ai), Fig 8 highlights how differences between Pi and Pij* are not uniform across space; the values at each origin are equivalent to ∑jf(cij). Recall, Pi is the number of workers at each TAZ (city-wide sum of 771,496) while Pij* is the number of workers who seek jobs (city-wide sum of 1,776,458) in that TAZ based on their travel behaviour. Pij* is an internal value of ai and the top plot presents the ratio of Pij* to Pi. It reflects how the effective opportunity-seeking population is sometimes inflated (i.e., impedance values is greater than 1) and others deflated (i.e., impedance value is less than 1) by the Shen-type measure (ai). As such, using Pij* to untangle the absolute job availability from ai instead of Pi can lead to exaggerating the total travel time in the city since it does not represent the actual number of workers but the effective number of workers. For instance, when trying to calculate the city-wide travel time using aiPij*, Shen-type accessibility yields 501,114.9 [h] instead of an interpretable city-wide travel time of 183,802.4 [h] that results if spatial availability Vi is used. Again, following the Shen-type accessibility definition, the absolute number of opportunities cannot be easily disentangled from ai.

Fig 8. The ratio of the effective opportunity seeking population to the population (top) and the average spatial availability’s balancing factor (Eq (9)) (bottom) for Toronto TAZ.

Fig 8

Black lines represent expressways and black dashed lines represent subway lines. All white TAZ have no worker population or jobs, i.e., with null accessibility values.

Not only are the number of available opportunities a direct result of Vi, the internal combined balancing factor Fijt (Eq (9)) can be used for analysis.

The bottom plot in Fig 8 demonstrates the average Fijt for each TAZ. Practically, the visualized values corresponds to the average proportion of opportunities available that are claimed by the zone based on travel behaviour and population competition for opportunities. These values can allow the analyst to understand the magnitude of the proportion of opportunities that the origin TAZ is assigned based on the opportunities located at reachable destination TAZ. For instance, the TAZ with the maximum value of 0.090 has many origin to destination trips (112 trips, upper 3rd quantile), many workers (5,538 workers, upper 3rd quantile), and is located centrally within Toronto. Averaging Fijt demonstrates that this TAZ claims on average a high proportion of jobs from reachable TAZ. This does not necessarily mean TAZ with a high Vi have an exceptionally high average Fijt; many TAZ around the downtown core have high Vi values but do not have exceptionally high average Fijt. The average Fijt can therefore be used to identify relatively “greedy” areas that could possibly withstand reductions in availability if spatial availability in areas with a deficit of jobs available is increased (through policy intervention). The balancing factor is an interesting feature of spatial availability that opens avenues for future analysis; alas, there does not seem to be an equivalent within the current formulation of the Shen-type measure.

Benchmarking opportunity availability

Fig 9 presents the number of jobs per capita for Hansen-type accessibility (top plot), the raw number of jobs per capita (middle plot), and the spatially available jobs per capita (bottom plot). For the purpose of discussion, a hypothetical benchmark of 1 job per capita is assumed for the city. The bottom plot displays the spatially available jobs per capita vi. This value is mathematically equivalent to the Shen-type measure ai, but with higher interpretability as a result of the proportional allocation mechanism. This mechanism makes clear that all the opportunities are allocated proportionally to origins and Vi values represent the number of available opportunities. Vi can be directly divided by the population at the origin and expressed as opportunities per capita vi. When spatial availability per capita (bottom plot) is compared to Hansen-type measure (top plot), dividing the output by population directly yields a more difficult to interpret number of unconstrained accessible jobs per capita. For instance, the median light-pink shaded TAZ corresponds to approximately 5.90 unconstrained accessible jobs per capita; this value is difficult to interpret because, as discussed in the Introduction Section, jobs are an exclusive opportunity types so their accessibility value should take into consideration competition.

Fig 9. Hansen-type accessible jobs per capita (top), number of jobs to population ratio (middle), and spatially available jobs per capita (bottom) for Toronto.

Fig 9

An arbitrary jobs-to-workers ratio is assumed to be 1 in the paper, this is the hypothetical opportunity availability benchmark. Black lines represent expressways and black dashed lines represent subway lines. All white TAZ have no worker population or jobs, i.e., with null accessibility values.

The spatially available jobs per capita vi (bottom plot) can also be used for benchmarking. The values can be compared directly to the raw number of jobs per capita (middle plot) since the total number of opportunities are preserved (and the population, in this case, is equivalent to the number of opportunities). For instance, a TAZ with a vi > 1 has more available jobs (based on travel behaviour and competition) than their working population. This TAZ has sufficient employment opportunities (under the assumptions of the input data), while a TAZ with a vi < 1 does not have sufficient employment opportunities. From an equity perspective, vi can be used to target where residential housing, job opportunities, and/or transportation system improvements should be created.

For TAZ with vi values significantly greater than 1 (dark pinks), constructing more residential housing for the type of workers who occupy the available jobs in the proximate TAZ should be considered. Assuming accurate and realistic input data, increasing the competition in the area will decrease the vi score, but it can be decreased up to threshold of vi = 1. For TAZ with vi values significantly less than 1 (light pinks), constructing more employment opportunities for the type of workers who live in proximate TAZ and/or prioritizing transportation network improvements to create more favourable travel time conditions can be considered.

Depending on the raw jobs per worker ratio, different approaches are appropriate. For instance, adding more residential locations near the downtown core (bottom center on the bottom plot) could be a good approach to increasing vi as there is already a high jobs per worker ratio (middle plot). However, doing so will decrease the vi availability in areas near the border of the city, so in addition, adding more employment opportunities to areas with low raw jobs per worker ratio and low vi is needed. Furthermore, the travel time landscape would also influence the resulting vi score, so transportation network improvements to areas with low vi could also be considered. This is to say, vi is dependent on the magnitude and spatial distribution of residential housing, job opportunities, and transportation system. The region could be optimized to achieve thresholds of specific vi values and thus the difference in residential housing, job opportunities, and transportation system can become policy intervention targets. It should also be kept in mind, that though vi = 1 and the comparison to the raw jobs per worker values can be used for intervention planning, vi can easily be transformed back to Vi to understand the magnitude of the job availability within that origin.

Conclusion

In this paper we show how Shen-type accessibility, a widely used measure of accessibility with competition, obscures some important internal values associated with ‘demanded’ opportunities. The Shen-type measure’s formulation confounds the population of origin-zones with the effective opportunity-seeking population. We propose an alternative derivation of accessibility with competition that we call spatial availability Vi. This measure ensures that opportunities are allocated in a proportional way and are preserved in the regional total. We demonstrate that spatial availability and Shen-type accessibility (along with 2SFCA) are equifinal: formally the equations can be made equivalent and can be considered as singly-constrained (and competitive) accessibility measures, however, spatial availability has the additional feature of proportional allocation. We argue the feature of proportional allocation improves interpretability of the final values and, as follows, the per capita opportunity spatial availability values (vi).

Why does spatial availability matter? Because competition in accessibility matters, so precise interpretation of the output is critical. Competition is an important consideration for certain opportunity types, and conventional Hansen-type accessibility does not capture it [34]. Through its intermediate values, spatial availability brings forward a different interpretation to competition than the Shen-type measure. As demonstrated in this paper, spatial availability increases interpretability by first presenting the absolute value of available jobs (Vi) and then by dividing the available jobs value by the number of working population (vi). This rate vi is equivalent to Shen-type measure but contains internal values, such as the proportional allocation mechanism, that yield more realistic estimates of opportunities taken.

Spatial availability’s proportional allocation is a result of its balancing factors; these balancing factors can also be used to better understand the absolute and rate values obtained. Spatial availability measure can be applied in many contexts, particularly in equity analysis and policy planning, fields where analysis of comparative and relative differences are pertinent. As shown in the empirical example, Hansen-type measure tends to result in values that are very extreme as a result of multiple-counting of opportunities. Multiple-counting may not be an issue if the opportunity-type is non-exclusive: but in the case of employment for example, where one worker can only take one job, the resulting values are difficult to interpret. In this respect, the increased interpretability and internal consistency of spatial availability can help to push accessibility analysis forward in ways Shen-type accessibility’s formulation cannot. For instance, an analyst may use spatial availability if they are interested in analysing the internal values of their accessibility analysis (e.g., which zones are the most and least competitive in terms of travel cost and demanding-population as informed by the balancing factors). Additionally analysts may use spatial availability to understand or benchmark the magnitude of spatially available opportunities of zones under current transportation system conditions or within possible policy scenarios. Based on the research presented, we suggest the following guidelines for the application of spatial availability and topics of future work:

  1. The Hansen-type accessibility should be used when opportunities are non-exclusive. When opportunities are exclusive (i.e., one opportunity spot for one person), the competitive accessibility measure of spatial availability should be strongly considered.

  2. Shen-type accessibility can be used to compute the availability of jobs (the rate and the absolute values if the original definition is corrected), however, if the analyst is interested in internal values and secondary analysis of the results, spatial availability should be considered.

  3. With the renewed interpretability of what the absolute opportunity availability is at each origin-zone, the spatial availability per capita vi value of 1 can be used as a policy goal: 1 opportunity per person. For areas with a value below 1, targeted increases to the quantity of opportunities, residential housing, and transportation system improvements can be considered such that the number of available jobs per capita in the zone is at least equal to 1. Since spatial availability per capita implicitly preserves the number of opportunities in the region, it can be directly compared to the region’s raw jobs to population ratio to inform policy. Additionally, the absolute values of spatial availability can be used to understand the magnitude of the opportunity availability deficit/surplus.

  4. Spatial availability per capita can also be compared directly to other regions as done by literature using Shen-type measure/2SFCA [9, 76, 77]. However, as a result of the renewed interpretation, the magnitude of spatially available opportunities can be quantified.

  5. Lastly, since opportunities are preserved, many new avenues of analysis can be pursued. This is especially important in light of emerging concerns regarding accessibility inequities. For instance, the population and opportunities can be segmented (i.e., transit users, active transportation users, low income, low education, new comers, children) and their spatial availability to opportunities can be assessed, benchmarked, and corresponding policy to target inequities can be theorized. As another example, the combined balancing factor can be analysed to identify which populations currently do not seek opportunities because of friction of distance.

Lastly, please view the S1 Appendix for the mathematical equivalence of spatial availability per capita (vi) and Shen-type accessibility (ai). This document provides a step-by-step solution of vi for population center A (from Shen’s synthetic example [35] as discussed in Section 2.3).

Supporting information

S1 Appendix

(PDF)

Data Availability

Data relevant to this study are available from Github at DOI:10.5281/zenodo.6450308 (https://soukhova.github.io/TTS2016R/) and the code at https://github.com/soukhova/Spatial-Availability-Measure.

Funding Statement

The lead author is supported by funding from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council’s (SSHRC) partnership grant: Mobilizing justice: towards evidence-based transportation equity policy and the SSHRC Canadian Graduate Scholarship - Doctoral award. The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript.

References

  • 1. Hansen WG. How Accessibility Shapes Land Use. Journal of the American Institute of Planners. 1959;25: 73–76. doi: 10.1080/01944365908978307 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 2. Handy SL, Niemeier DA. Measuring Accessibility: An Exploration of Issues and Alternatives. Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space. 1997;29: 1175–1194. doi: 10.1068/a291175 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 3. Weber J, Kwan MP. Evaluating the effects of geographic contexts on individual accessibility: A multilevel approach. Urban Geography. 2003;24: 647–671. Available: ISI: 000221150900001. doi: 10.2747/0272-3638.24.8.647 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 4. Farber S, Neutens T, Miller HJ, Li X. The social interaction potential of metropoli-tan regions: A time-geographic measurement approach using joint accessibility. Annals of the Association of American Geographers. 2013;103: 483–504. doi: 10.1080/00045608.2012.689238 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 5. Páez A, Mercado R, Farber S, Morency C, Roorda M. Accessibility to health care facilities in montreal island: An application of relative accessibility indicators from the perspective of senior and non-senior residents. International Journal of Health Geographics. 2010;9: 1–9. Available: http://www.ij-healthgeographics.com/content/9/1/52 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 6. Wang FH. Measurement, optimization, and impact of health care accessibility: A methodological review. Annals of the Association of American Geographers. 2012;102: 1104–1112. doi: 10.1080/00045608.2012.657146 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 7. Delamater PL. Spatial accessibility in suboptimally configured health care systems: A modified two-step floating catchment area (M2SFCA) metric. Health & Place. 2013;24: 30–43. doi: 10.1016/j.healthplace.2013.07.012 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 8. Pereira RHM, Braga CKV, Servo LM, Serra B, Amaral P, Gouveia N, et al. Geographic access to COVID-19 healthcare in brazil using a balanced float catchment area approach. Social Science & Medicine. 2021;273: 113773. doi: 10.1016/j.socscimed.2021.113773 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 9. Zhang D, Zhang G, Zhou C. Differences in Accessibility of Public Health Facilities in Hierarchical Municipalities and the Spatial Pattern Characteristics of Their Services in Doumen District, China. Land. 2021;10: 1249. doi: 10.3390/land10111249 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 10. Yang J, Bao Y, Zhang Y, Li X, Ge Q. Impact of accessibility on housing prices in dalian city of china based on a geographically weighted regression model. Chinese geographical science. 2018;28: 505–515. doi: 10.1007/s11769-018-0954-6 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 11. Jin S, Yang J, Wang E, Liu J. The influence of high-speed rail on ice-snow tourism in northeastern china. Tourism Management. 2020;78: 104070. doi: 10.1016/j.tourman.2019.104070 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 12.Sathisan SK, Srinivasan N. Evaluation of accessibility of urban transporta-tion networks. Transportation Research Record. 1998; 78–83. Available: ISI:000081981500011 C:/Papers/Transportation Research Record/TRR (1998)1617 78-83.pdf.
  • 13. Geurs KT, van Wee B. Accessibility evaluation of land-use and transport strategies: review and research directions. Journal of Transport Geography. 2004;12: 127140. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2003.10.005 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 14. Shi Y, Blainey S, Sun C, Jing P. A literature review on accessibility using bibliometric analysis techniques. Journal of Transport Geography. 2020;87: 102810. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2020.102810 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 15. Deboosere R, El-Geneidy AM, Levinson D. Accessibility-oriented de-velopment. Journal of Transport Geography. 2018;70: 11–20. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2018.05.015 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 16. Handy S. Is accessibility an idea whose time has finally come? Trans-portation Research Part D: Transport and Environment. 2020;83: 102319. doi: 10.1016/j.trd.2020.102319 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 17. Proffitt DG, Bartholomew K, Ewing R, Miller HJ. Accessibility planning in American metropolitan areas: Are we there yet? Urban Studies. 2017;56: 167192. 10.1177/0042098017710122 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 18. Yan X. Toward Accessibility-Based Planning. Journal of the American Planning Association. 2021;87: 409–423. doi: 10.1080/01944363.2020.1850321 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 19. Harris CD. The Market as a Factor in the Localization of Industry in the United States. Annals of the Association of American Geographers. 1954;44: 315–348. Available: https://www.jstor.org/stable/2561395 [Google Scholar]
  • 20. Wilson AG. A Family of Spatial Interaction Models, and Associated Devel-opments. Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space. 1971;3: 1–32. doi: 10.1068/a030001 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 21. Cervero R, Sandoval O, Landis J. Transportation as a Stimulus of Welfare-to-Work: Private versus Public Mobility. Journal of Planning Education and Research. 2002;22: 50–63. doi: 10.1177/0739456X0202200105 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 22. Paez A. Network accessibility and the spatial distribution of economic activity in eastern asia. Urban Studies. 2004;41: 2211–2230. doi: 10.1080/0042098042000268429 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 23. Levinson DM. Accessibility and the journey to work. Journal of Transport Geography. 1998;6: 11–21. doi: 10.1016/S0966-6923(97)00036-7 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 24. Arranz-López A, Soria-Lara JA, Witlox F, Páez A. Measuring relative non-motorized accessibility to retail activities. International Journal of Sustainable Transportation. 2019;13: 639–651. doi: 10.1080/15568318.2018.1498563 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 25. Yang J, Guo A, Li X, Huang T. Study of the Impact of a High-Speed Railway Opening on China’s Accessibility Pattern and Spatial Equality. Sustainability. 2018;10: 2943. 10.3390/su10082943 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 26. Miller EJ. Accessibility: measurement and application in transportation planning. Transport Reviews. 2018;38: 551–555. doi: 10.1080/01441647.2018.1492778 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 27. Allen J, Farber S. A Measure of Competitive Access to Destinations for Com-paring Across Multiple Study Regions. Geographical Analysis. 2019;52: 69–86. doi: 10.1111/gean.12188 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 28. Campbell KB, Rising JA, Klopp JM, Mbilo JM. Accessibility across transport modes and residential developments in nairobi. Journal of Transport Geography. 2019;74: 77–90. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2018.08.002 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 29. Bocarejo S. JP, Oviedo H. DR. Transport accessibility and social inequities: A tool for identification of mobility needs and evaluation of transport investments. Journal of Transport Geography. 2012;24: 142–154. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2011.12.004 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 30. El-Geneidy A, Levinson D, Diab E, Boisjoly G, Verbich D, Loong C. The cost of equity: Assessing transit accessibility and social disparity using total travel cost. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice. 2016;91: 302–316. [Google Scholar]
  • 31. Jiang H, Levinson DM. Accessibility and the evaluation of investments on the beijing subway. Journal of Transport and Land Use. 2016;10. doi: 10.5198/jtlu.2016.884 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 32. Hu Y, Downs J. Measuring and visualizing place-based space-time job accessibility. Journal of Transport Geography. 2019;74: 278–288. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2018.12.002 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 33. Kelobonye K, Zhou H, McCarney G, Xia J. Measuring the accessibility and spatial equity of urban services under competition using the cumulative opportunities measure. Journal of Transport Geography. 2020;85: 102706. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2020.102706 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 34. Merlin LA, Hu L. Does competition matter in measures of job accessibility? Explaining employment in los angeles. Journal of Transport Geography. 2017;64: 77–88. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2017.08.009 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 35. Shen Q. Location characteristics of inner-city neighborhoods and employment accessibility of low-wage workers. Environment and Planning B: Planning and Design. 1998;25: 345–365. doi: 10.1068/b250345 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 36. Paez A, Higgins CD, Vivona SF. Demand and level of service inflation in Floating Catchment Area (FCA) methods. Shah TI, editor. PLOS ONE. 2019;14: e0218773. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0218773 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 37. Weibull JW. An axiomatic approach to the measurement of accessibility. Regional Science and Urban Economics. 1976;6: 357–379. doi: 10.1016/0166-0462(76)90031-4 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 38. Joseph AE, Bantock PR. Rural Accessibility of General Practitioners: the Case of Bruce and Grey Counties, ONTARIO, 1901-1981. The Canadian Geographer/Le Geographe canadien. 1984;28: 226–239. doi: 10.1111/j.1541-0064.1984.tb00788.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 39. Luo W, Wang F. Measures of Spatial Accessibility to Health Care in a GIS Environment: Synthesis and a Case Study in the Chicago Region. Environment and Planning B: Planning and Design. 2003;30: 865–884. doi: 10.1068/b29120 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 40. Yang D-H, Goerge R, Mullner R. Comparing GIS-Based Methods of Measuring Spatial Accessibility to Health Services. Journal of Medical Systems. 2006;30: 23–32. doi: 10.1007/s10916-006-7400-5 [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 41. Chen Z, Zhou X, Yeh AG. Spatial accessibility to kindergartens using a spectrum combinational approach: Case study of Shanghai using cellphone data. Environment and Planning B: Urban Analytics and City Science. 2020; 239980832095422. 10.1177/2399808320954221 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 42. Ye C, Zhu Y, Yang J, Fu Q. Spatial equity in accessing secondary education: Evidence from a gravity-based model: Spatial equity in accessing secondary education. The Canadian Géographer / Le Geographe canadien. 2018;62: 452469. 10.1111/cag.12482 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 43. Chen X. Enhancing the Two-Step Floating Catchment Area Model for Community Food Access Mapping: Case of the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program. The Professional Geographer. 2019;71: 668–680. doi: 10.1080/00330124.2019.1578978 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 44. Chen BY, Cheng X-P, Kwan M-P, Schwanen T. Evaluating spatial accessibility to healthcare services under travel time uncertainty: A reliability-based floating catchment area approach. Journal of Transport Geography. 2020;87: 102794. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2020.102794 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 45. Hu L. Changing Job Access of the Poor: Effects of Spatial and Socioeconomic Transformations in Chicago, 1990-2010. Urban Studies. 2014;51: 675–692. doi: 10.1177/0042098013492229 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 46. Tao Z, Zhou J, Lin X, Chao H, Li G. Investigating the impacts of public transport on job accessibility in Shenzhen, China: A multi-modal approach. LAND USE POLICY. 2020;99. [Google Scholar]
  • 47. Brunsdon C, Comber A. Opening practice: Supporting reproducibility and crit-ical spatial data science. Journal of Geographical Systems. 2021;23: 477–496. doi: 10.1007/s10109-020-00334-2 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 48. Páez A. Open spatial sciences: An introduction. Journal of Geographical Systems. 2021;23: 467–476. doi: 10.1007/s10109-021-00364-4 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 49. Arribas-Bel D, Green M, Rowe F, Singleton A. Open data products-a framework for creating valuable analysis ready data. Journal of Geographical Systems. 2021;23: 497–514. doi: 10.1007/s10109-021-00363-5 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 50.Soukhov A, Paez A. TTS2016R: An augmented 2016 transportation tomorrow survey (TTS) data package: Worker and place of employment counts, trips and estimated travel time to work in the greater golden horsehoe area, canada. 2022. Available: https://soukhova.github.io/TTS2016R/.
  • 51.Soukhov A, Paez A, Higgins CD. GitHub Repository: Introducing spatial avail-ability, a singly-constrained measure of competitive accessibility. 2022. Available: https://github.com/soukhova/Spatial-Availability-Measure. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed]
  • 52. Paez A, Scott DM, Morency C. Measuring accessibility: Positive and normative implementations of various accessibility indicators. Journal of Transport Geography. 2012;25: 141–153. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2012.03.016 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 53. Rosik P, Goliszek S, Komornicki T, Duma P. Forecast of the Impact of Electric Car Battery Performance and Infrastructural and Demographic Changes on Cumulative Accessibility for the Five Most Populous Cities in Poland. Energies. 2021;14: 8350. doi: 10.3390/en14248350 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 54. Qi Y, Fan Y, Sun T, Hu L(Ivy). Decade-long changes in spatial mis-match in Beijing, China: Are disadvantaged populations better or worse off? Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space. 2018;50: 848–868. doi: 10.1177/0308518X18755747 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 55. Kwan M-P. Space-Time and Integral Measures of Individual Accessibility: A Comparative Analysis Using a Point-based Framework. Geographical Analysis. 1998;30: 191–216. doi: 10.1111/j.1538-4632.1998.tb00396.x [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 56. Vale DS, Pereira M. The influence of the impedance function on gravity-based pedestrian accessibility measures: A comparative analysis. Environment and Planning B: Urban Analytics and City Science. 2017;44: 740–763. 10.1177/0265813516641685 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 57. Reggiani A, Bucci P, Russo G. Accessibility and Impedance Forms: Empirical Applications to the German Commuting Network. International Regional Science Review. 2011;34: 230–252. doi: 10.1177/0160017610387296 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 58. Li A, Huang Y, Axhausen KW. An approach to imputing destination activities for inclusion in measures of bicycle accessibility. Journal of Transport Geography. 2020;82: 102566. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2019.102566 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 59. Higgins CD. Accessibility toolbox for r and ArcGIS. Transport Findings. 2019. doi: 10.32866/8416 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 60. Santana Palacios M, El-geneidy A. Cumulative versus Gravity-based Accessibility Measures: Which One to Use? Findings. 2022. doi: 10.32866/001c.32444 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 61. Barboza MHC, Carneiro MS, Falavigna C, Luz G, Orrico R. Balancing time: Using a new accessibility measure in Rio de Janeiro. Journal of Transport Geography. 2021;90: 102924. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2020.102924 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 62. Pereira RHM, Banister D, Schwanen T, Wessel N. Distributional effects of trans-port policies on inequalities in access to opportunities in Rio de Janeiro. Journal of Transport and Land Use. 2019;12. doi: 10.5198/jtlu.2019.1523 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 63. Wang S, Wang M, Liu Y. Access to urban parks: Comparing spatial accessibility measures using three GIS-based approaches. Computers, Environment and Urban Systems. 2021;90: 101713. doi: 10.1016/j.compenvurbsys.2021.101713 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 64. Ortuzar JD, Willumsen LG. Modelling transport. New York: Wiley; 2011. [Google Scholar]
  • 65.Williams HCWL. Travel demand forecasting: An overview of theoretical develop-ments. In: Banister DJ, Hall PG, editors. Transport and public policy planning. Mansell; 1981.
  • 66. Sarlas G, Paez A, Axhausen KW. Betweenness-accessibility: Estimating impacts of accessibility on networks. Journal of Transport Geography. 2020;84: 12. doi: 10.1016/j.jtrangeo.2020.102680 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 67.Data Management Group. TTS—Transportation Tomorrow Survey 2016. 2018. Available: http://dmg.utoronto.ca/transportation-tomorrow-survey/tts-introduction.
  • 68.Rafael H. M. Pereira, Marcus Saraiva, Daniel Herszenhut, Carlos Kaue Vieira Braga, Matthew Wigginton Conway. r5r: Rapid realistic routing on multimodal transport networks with R5 in r. Findings. 2021. 10.32866/001c.21262 [DOI]
  • 69.OpenStreetMap Street Network Extracts: Canada. 2021. Available: https://download.geofabrik.de/north-america/canada.html.
  • 70. Allen J, Farber S. Suburbanization of Transport Poverty. Annals of the American Association of Geographers. 2021;111: 18. [Google Scholar]
  • 71. Higgins CD, Páez A, Ki G, Wang J. Changes in accessibility to emergency and community food services during COVID-19 and implications for low income populations in hamilton, ontario. Social Science & Medicine. 2021; 114442. doi: 10.1016/j.socscimed.2021.114442 [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • 72. Lopez FA, Páez A. Spatial clustering of high-tech manufacturing and knowledge-intensive service firms in the greater toronto area. Canadian Geographer-Geographe Canadien. 2017;61: 240–252. doi: 10.1111/cag.12326 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 73. Horbachov P, Svichynskyi S. Theoretical substantiation of trip length distribution for home-based work trips in urban transit systems. Journal of Transport and Land Use. 2018;11: 593–632. Available: https://www.jstor.org/stable/26622420 [Google Scholar]
  • 74. Batista SFA, Leclercq L, Geroliminis N. Estimation of regional trip length distributions for the calibration of the aggregated network traffic models. Transportation Research Part B: Methodological. 2019;122: 192–217. doi: 10.1016/j.trb.2019.02.009 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 75. Delignette-Muller ML, Dutang C. fitdistrplus: An R package for fitting dis-tributions. Journal of Statistical Software. 2015;64: 1–34. Available: https://www.jstatsoft.org/article/view/v064i04 [Google Scholar]
  • 76. Giannotti M, Barros J, Tomasiello DB, Smith D, Pizzol B, Santos BM, et al. Inequalities in transit accessibility: Contributions from a comparative study between Global South and North metropolitan regions. Cities. 2021;109: 103016. doi: 10.1016/j.cities.2020.103016 [DOI] [Google Scholar]
  • 77. Zhou C, Zhang D, He X. Transportation Accessibility Evaluation of Educational Institutions Conducting Field Environmental Education Activities in Ecological Protection Areas: A Case Study of Zhuhai City. Sustainability. 2021;13: 9392. 10.3390/su13169392 [DOI] [Google Scholar]

Decision Letter 0

Jun Yang

12 Sep 2022

PONE-D-22-24454Introducing spatial availability, a singly-constrained measure of competitive accessibilityPLOS ONE

Dear Dr. Soukhov,

Thank you for submitting your manuscript to PLOS ONE. After careful consideration, we feel that it has merit but does not fully meet PLOS ONE’s publication criteria as it currently stands. Therefore, we invite you to submit a revised version of the manuscript that addresses the points raised during the review process.

Please submit your revised manuscript by Oct 27 2022 11:59PM. If you will need more time than this to complete your revisions, please reply to this message or contact the journal office at plosone@plos.org. When you're ready to submit your revision, log on to https://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/ and select the 'Submissions Needing Revision' folder to locate your manuscript file.

Please include the following items when submitting your revised manuscript:

  • A rebuttal letter that responds to each point raised by the academic editor and reviewer(s). You should upload this letter as a separate file labeled 'Response to Reviewers'.

  • A marked-up copy of your manuscript that highlights changes made to the original version. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Revised Manuscript with Track Changes'.

  • An unmarked version of your revised paper without tracked changes. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Manuscript'.

If you would like to make changes to your financial disclosure, please include your updated statement in your cover letter. Guidelines for resubmitting your figure files are available below the reviewer comments at the end of this letter.

If applicable, we recommend that you deposit your laboratory protocols in protocols.io to enhance the reproducibility of your results. Protocols.io assigns your protocol its own identifier (DOI) so that it can be cited independently in the future. For instructions see: https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/submission-guidelines#loc-laboratory-protocols. Additionally, PLOS ONE offers an option for publishing peer-reviewed Lab Protocol articles, which describe protocols hosted on protocols.io. Read more information on sharing protocols at https://plos.org/protocols?utm_medium=editorial-email&utm_source=authorletters&utm_campaign=protocols.

We look forward to receiving your revised manuscript.

Kind regards,

Jun Yang

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Journal Requirements:

When submitting your revision, we need you to address these additional requirements.

1. Please ensure that your manuscript meets PLOS ONE's style requirements, including those for file naming. The PLOS ONE style templates can be found at 

https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=wjVg/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_main_body.pdf and 

https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=ba62/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_title_authors_affiliations.pdf

2. Thank you for stating the following financial disclosure: 

"The Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council’s partnership grant: Mobilizing justice:

towards evidence-based transportation equity policy."

  

Please state what role the funders took in the study.  If the funders had no role, please state: "The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript." 

If this statement is not correct you must amend it as needed. 

Please include this amended Role of Funder statement in your cover letter; we will change the online submission form on your behalf.

3. In your Data Availability statement, you have not specified where the minimal data set underlying the results described in your manuscript can be found. PLOS defines a study's minimal data set as the underlying data used to reach the conclusions drawn in the manuscript and any additional data required to replicate the reported study findings in their entirety. All PLOS journals require that the minimal data set be made fully available. For more information about our data policy, please see http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/data-availability.

"Upon re-submitting your revised manuscript, please upload your study’s minimal underlying data set as either Supporting Information files or to a stable, public repository and include the relevant URLs, DOIs, or accession numbers within your revised cover letter. For a list of acceptable repositories, please see http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/data-availability#loc-recommended-repositories. Any potentially identifying patient information must be fully anonymized.

Important: If there are ethical or legal restrictions to sharing your data publicly, please explain these restrictions in detail. Please see our guidelines for more information on what we consider unacceptable restrictions to publicly sharing data: http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/data-availability#loc-unacceptable-data-access-restrictions. Note that it is not acceptable for the authors to be the sole named individuals responsible for ensuring data access.

We will update your Data Availability statement to reflect the information you provide in your cover letter.

4. We note that Figures 3,4,5,7,8 and 9 in your submission contain copyrighted images. All PLOS content is published under the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY 4.0), which means that the manuscript, images, and Supporting Information files will be freely available online, and any third party is permitted to access, download, copy, distribute, and use these materials in any way, even commercially, with proper attribution. For more information, see our copyright guidelines: http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/licenses-and-copyright.

We require you to either (1) present written permission from the copyright holder to publish these figures specifically under the CC BY 4.0 license, or (2) remove the figures from your submission:

a. You may seek permission from the original copyright holder of Figures 3,4,5,7,8 and 9 to publish the content specifically under the CC BY 4.0 license. 

We recommend that you contact the original copyright holder with the Content Permission Form (http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=7c09/content-permission-form.pdf) and the following text:

“I request permission for the open-access journal PLOS ONE to publish XXX under the Creative Commons Attribution License (CCAL) CC BY 4.0 (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/). Please be aware that this license allows unrestricted use and distribution, even commercially, by third parties. Please reply and provide explicit written permission to publish XXX under a CC BY license and complete the attached form.”

Please upload the completed Content Permission Form or other proof of granted permissions as an "Other" file with your submission. 

In the figure caption of the copyrighted figure, please include the following text: “Reprinted from [ref] under a CC BY license, with permission from [name of publisher], original copyright [original copyright year].”

b. If you are unable to obtain permission from the original copyright holder to publish these figures under the CC BY 4.0 license or if the copyright holder’s requirements are incompatible with the CC BY 4.0 license, please either i) remove the figure or ii) supply a replacement figure that complies with the CC BY 4.0 license. Please check copyright information on all replacement figures and update the figure caption with source information. If applicable, please specify in the figure caption text when a figure is similar but not identical to the original image and is therefore for illustrative purposes only.

The following resources for replacing copyrighted map figures may be helpful:

USGS National Map Viewer (public domain): http://viewer.nationalmap.gov/viewer/

The Gateway to Astronaut Photography of Earth (public domain): http://eol.jsc.nasa.gov/sseop/clickmap/

Maps at the CIA (public domain): https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/index.html and https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/cia-maps-publications/index.html

NASA Earth Observatory (public domain): http://earthobservatory.nasa.gov/

Landsat: http://landsat.visibleearth.nasa.gov/

USGS EROS (Earth Resources Observatory and Science (EROS) Center) (public domain): http://eros.usgs.gov/#

Natural Earth (public domain): http://www.naturalearthdata.com/

Additional Editor Comments:

Major Revision

[Note: HTML markup is below. Please do not edit.]

Reviewers' comments:

Reviewer's Responses to Questions

Comments to the Author

1. Is the manuscript technically sound, and do the data support the conclusions?

The manuscript must describe a technically sound piece of scientific research with data that supports the conclusions. Experiments must have been conducted rigorously, with appropriate controls, replication, and sample sizes. The conclusions must be drawn appropriately based on the data presented.

Reviewer #1: Yes

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

2. Has the statistical analysis been performed appropriately and rigorously?

Reviewer #1: Yes

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

3. Have the authors made all data underlying the findings in their manuscript fully available?

The PLOS Data policy requires authors to make all data underlying the findings described in their manuscript fully available without restriction, with rare exception (please refer to the Data Availability Statement in the manuscript PDF file). The data should be provided as part of the manuscript or its supporting information, or deposited to a public repository. For example, in addition to summary statistics, the data points behind means, medians and variance measures should be available. If there are restrictions on publicly sharing data—e.g. participant privacy or use of data from a third party—those must be specified.

Reviewer #1: Yes

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

4. Is the manuscript presented in an intelligible fashion and written in standard English?

PLOS ONE does not copyedit accepted manuscripts, so the language in submitted articles must be clear, correct, and unambiguous. Any typographical or grammatical errors should be corrected at revision, so please note any specific errors here.

Reviewer #1: Yes

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

5. Review Comments to the Author

Please use the space provided to explain your answers to the questions above. You may also include additional comments for the author, including concerns about dual publication, research ethics, or publication ethics. (Please upload your review as an attachment if it exceeds 20,000 characters)

Reviewer #1: The authors demonstrated how a widely used measure of accessibility with congestion fails

to properly match the opportunity-seeking population.

Please highlight the key points in the abstract.

The introduction should further highlight the scientific problems, motivations, and possible innovations of the paper.

What is the contribution and why the contribution is important?

The results should be better described, discussed and justified. I suggest the results should be better discussed and justified, such as whether they are consistent with previous studies or analyzing the reasons for the empirical results. please read

The influence of high-speed rail on ice–snow tourism in northeastern China. Tourism Management(2020), doi:10.1016/j.tourman.2019.104070.

Study on the Impact of High-speed Railway Opening on China's Accessibility Pattern and Spatial Equality[J].Sustainability 2018,10,2943. doi:10.3390/su10082943 .

The Impact of Accessibility on House Prices Based on a Geographically Weighted Regression Model[J]. Chinese Geographical Science,2018,28(3):505-515. doi: 10.1007/s11769-018-0954-6

Reviewer #2: The authors used the data from Transportation Tomorrow Survey to explore the application of spatial availability and compare it to other relevant measures. The manuscript is valid and innovative. However, there also have some problems need to be solved.

1.In introduction, the authors only inserted the serial number of the references. The presentation is omitted. It is not standard enough.

2.There are many methods to measure the accessibility. What's the advantage and disadvantage of the improved methods compared with other methods, such as space syntax and potential model.

3.Some relevant references should be cited as follow:

Impact of Accessibility on Housing Prices in Dalian City of China Based on a Geographically Weighted Regression Model.Chin. Geogra. Sci. 2018 Vol. 28 No. 3 pp. 505–515 .https://doi.org/10.1007/s11769-018-0954-6

The influence of the spatial pattern of urban road networks on the quality of business environments: the case of Dalian

City. Environment, Development and Sustainability (2022) 24:9429–9446.https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-021-01832-z

Differences in Accessibility of Public Health Facilities in Hierarchical Municipalities and the Spatial Pattern Characteristics of Their Services in Doumen District,China. Land 2021, 10, 1249. https://doi.org/10.3390/land10111249.

Transportation Accessibility Evaluation of Educational Institutions Conducting Field Environmental Education Activities in Ecological Protection Areas: A Case Study of Zhuhai City. Sustainability 2021, 13, 9392. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13169392.

**********

6. PLOS authors have the option to publish the peer review history of their article (what does this mean?). If published, this will include your full peer review and any attached files.

If you choose “no”, your identity will remain anonymous but your review may still be made public.

Do you want your identity to be public for this peer review? For information about this choice, including consent withdrawal, please see our Privacy Policy.

Reviewer #1: No

Reviewer #2: No

**********

[NOTE: If reviewer comments were submitted as an attachment file, they will be attached to this email and accessible via the submission site. Please log into your account, locate the manuscript record, and check for the action link "View Attachments". If this link does not appear, there are no attachment files.]

While revising your submission, please upload your figure files to the Preflight Analysis and Conversion Engine (PACE) digital diagnostic tool, https://pacev2.apexcovantage.com/. PACE helps ensure that figures meet PLOS requirements. To use PACE, you must first register as a user. Registration is free. Then, login and navigate to the UPLOAD tab, where you will find detailed instructions on how to use the tool. If you encounter any issues or have any questions when using PACE, please email PLOS at figures@plos.org. Please note that Supporting Information files do not need this step.

PLoS One. 2023 Jan 20;18(1):e0278468. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0278468.r002

Author response to Decision Letter 0


24 Oct 2022

Journal Requirements

1. Please ensure that your manuscript meets PLOS ONE's style requirements, including those for file naming. The PLOS ONE style templates can be found at

https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=wjVg/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_main_body.pdf and https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=ba62/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_title_authors_affiliations.pdf

• Thank you for this comment. We produced the manuscript using the .tex style template for PLOS ONE.

2. Thank you for stating the following financial disclosure: "The Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council’s partnership grant: Mobilizing justice: towards evidence-based transportation equity policy."

Please state what role the funders took in the study. If the funders had no role, please state: "The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish, or preparation of the manuscript." If this statement is not correct you must amend it as needed. Please include this amended Role of Funder statement in your cover letter; we will change the online submission form on your behalf.

• Thank you for this comment. We’ve updated the statement accordingly and included it in the revised cover letter.

3. In your Data Availability statement, you have not specified where the minimal data set underlying the results described in your manuscript can be found. PLOS defines a study's minimal data set as the underlying data used to reach the conclusions drawn in the manuscript and any additional data required to replicate the reported study findings in their entirety. All PLOS journals require that the minimal data set be made fully available. For more information about our data policy, please see http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/data-availability.

"Upon re-submitting your revised manuscript, please upload your study’s minimal underlying data set as either Supporting Information files or to a stable, public repository and include the relevant URLs, DOIs, or accession numbers within your revised cover letter. For a list of acceptable repositories, please see http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/data-availability#loc-recommended-repositories. Any potentially identifying patient information must be fully anonymized.

Important: If there are ethical or legal restrictions to sharing your data publicly, please explain these restrictions in detail. Please see our guidelines for more information on what we consider unacceptable restrictions to publicly sharing data: http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/data-availability#loc-unacceptable-data-access-restrictions. Note that it is not acceptable for the authors to be the sole named individuals responsible for ensuring data access. We will update your Data Availability statement to reflect the information you provide in your cover letter.

• Thank you for this comment. The data set is available from https://soukhova.github.io/TTS2016R/ The full manuscript and the code are included in this repository: https://github.com/soukhova/Spatial-Availability-Measure. Both links are provided as footnotes in the Introduction section.

4. We note that Figures 3,4,5,7,8 and 9 in your submission contain copyrighted images. All PLOS content is published under the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY 4.0), which means that the manuscript, images, and Supporting Information files will be freely available online, and any third party is permitted to access, download, copy, distribute, and use these materials in any way, even commercially, with proper attribution. For more information, see our copyright guidelines: http://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/licenses-and-copyright.

We require you to either (1) present written permission from the copyright holder to publish these figures specifically under the CC BY 4.0 license, or (2) remove the figures from your submission.

• Thank you for this comment. All images are original and were generated by us using the data sources stated in the manuscript using code found in the .Rmd file in the repository (https://github.com/soukhova/Spatial-Availability-Measure/blob/main/Spatial-Availability-Paper/Spatial-Availability-Paper.Rmd). The packages used to produce the figures are cited.

Reviewer #1

The authors demonstrated how a widely used measure of accessibility with congestion fails to properly match the opportunity-seeking population.

1. Please highlight the key points in the abstract.

• Thanks for this comment. We modified the abstract to highlight the key points of this paper. The abstract now reads as follows:

Accessibility indicators are widely used in transportation, urban, and healthcare planning, among many other applications. These measures are weighted sums of reachable opportunities from a given origin conditional on the cost of movement, and are estimates of the potential for spatial interaction. Over time, various proposals have been forwarded to improve their interpretability: one of those methodological additions have been the introduction of competition. In this paper, we focus on competition, but first demonstrate how a widely used measure of accessibility with congestion fails to properly match the opportunity-seeking population. We then propose an alternative formulation of accessibility with competition, a measure we call _spatial availability_. This measure relies on proportional allocation balancing factors (friction of distance and population competition) that are equivalent to imposing a single constraint on conventional gravity-based accessibility. In other words, the proportional allocation of opportunities results in a _spatially available opportunities_ value which is assigned to each origin that, when all origin values are summed, equals the total number of opportunities in the region. We also demonstrate how Two-Stage Floating Catchment Area (2SFCA) methods are equivalent to spatial availability and can be reconceptualized as singly-constrained accessibility. To illustrate the application of spatial availability and compare it to other relevant measures, we use data from the 2016 Transportation Tomorrow Survey of the Greater Golden Horseshoe area in southern Ontario, Canada. Spatial availability is an important contribution since it clarifies the interpretation of accessibility with competition and paves the way for future applications in equity analysis.

2. The introduction should further highlight the scientific problems, motivations, and possible innovations of the paper.

• Thank you for these points. We modified the text as follows to include the highlighted motivations (as a result of the scientific problems) at the end of the introduction.

The key motivations of this paper are as follows:

- To address and improve on the interpretability of Hansen-type accessibility measure; and

- To consider competition from the perspective of the population for opportunities within an accessibility measure.

• We’d like to draw your attention to the summary of the objectives of the paper in the revised version of the manuscript and included as follows. We believe these correctly highlight the possible innovations of this paper.

In this way, the aim of the paper is three-fold:

- First, we aim to demonstrate that Shen-type (and thus @weibull_axiomatic_1976 accessibility and the popular 2SFCA methods) produce equivocal estimates of opportunities allocated as the result is presented as a rate (i.e., opportunities per capita);

- Second, we introduce a new measure, _spatial availability_, which we submit is a more interpretable alternative to Shen-type accessibility, since opportunities in the system are preserved and proportionally allocated to the population; and

- Third, we show how Shen-type accessibility (and 2SFCA methods) can be seen as measures of singly-constrained accessibility.

3. What is the contribution and why the contribution is important?

• An important question to ask indeed! We believe we highlight the contribution and its importance throughout the paper, particularly in subsection “Why does proportional allocation matter?” as well as in the conclusion. The contribution is in the conclusion is summarized as follows:

In this paper we show how a widely used measure of accessibility with competition (Shen-type accessibility) obscures some important internal values of opportunities taken. This is caused by confounding the population of zones with the _effective opportunity-seeking population_. We then propose an alternative derivation of accessibility with competition that we call spatial availability. This measure ensures that opportunities are allocated in a proportional way and preserved in the regional total. We also show that spatial availability and Shen-type accessibility are equifinal: formally the equations are the same (along with 2SFCA) and can be consider as singly-constrained measures.

• In addition, following your suggestion, we edited the first few sentences of the conclusion’s second paragraph to make the importance of the contribution more clear. It now reads:

Spatial availability matters because competition is an important consideration for certain opportunity types and conventional Hansen-type accessibility does not capture it [@merlin2017competition]. Spatial availability also brings forward a different interpretation to competition than the Shen-type measure through its output value, the proportional allocation factors, and the output values per capita. In equity analysis and policy planning, an analyst might be interested in the internal values of their accessibility analysis, for example travel times, and who pays how much for accessibility. The increased interpretability and internal consistency of spatial availability can help to push accessibility analysis forward. Hansen-type measure tend to result in values which are very extreme as a result of multiple-counting opportunities as shown in empirical example. Multiple-counting may not be an issue if the opportunity-type is non-exclusive, but with the case of employment where one worker can only take one job, the resulting values are difficult to interpret (though it can be interpreted relatively to speak about urban form). In this paper, we also demonstrated how attempting to disentangle the absolute values of opportunities from the Shen-type measure is difficult as a result of Shen's definition which confounds the population with the effective-opportunity seeking population.

• We also added a sentence to the abstract which states the contribution of the paper more clearly, as inspired by this comment. The most current version of the abstract is included in reply to your comment 1.

4. The results should be better described, discussed and justified. I suggest the results should be better discussed and justified, such as whether they are consistent with previous studies or analyzing the reasons for the empirical results. please read:

• The influence of high-speed rail on ice–snow tourism in northeastern China. Tourism Management(2020), doi:10.1016/j.tourman.2019.104070

• Study on the Impact of High-speed Railway Opening on China's Accessibility Pattern and Spatial Equality[J].Sustainability 2018,10,2943. doi:10.3390/su10082943

• The Impact of Accessibility on House Prices Based on a Geographically Weighted Regression Model[J]. Chinese Geographical Science,2018,28(3):505-515. doi: 10.1007/s11769-018-0954-6

• Thank you for these references. They have been included in the revised version of the paper as examples of the important role that accessibility analysis plays in different disciplines.

Reviewer #2

The authors used the data from Transportation Tomorrow Survey to explore the application of spatial availability and compare it to other relevant measures. The manuscript is valid and innovative. However, there also have some problems need to be solved.

1. In introduction, the authors only inserted the serial number of the references. The presentation is omitted. It is not standard enough.

• Thank you for this comment. We are advised to use the in-text referencing style of PLoS ONE, which uses serial number of the reference.

2. There are many methods to measure the accessibility. What's the advantage and disadvantage of the improved methods compared with other methods, such as space syntax and potential model.

• Thank you for these points, discussing the advantages and disadvantages of similar methods is important to contextualize the improved method. In this paper, we do discuss other accessibility measures at length in the ‘Accessibility measures revisited’ section. We outline Hansen-type accessibility and then Shen-type accessibility, both of which are forms of potential accessibility. We introduce spatial availability in the following section and then discuss its advantages in the subsection ‘Why does proportional allocation matter?”.

• Our aim is to present a new accessibility measure, spatial availability, and we discuss its properties in reference to two comparable measures, Hansen-type accessibility, and Shen-type accessibility (2SFCA). These two are forms of potential accessibility (see for an example Zhang et al., 2021). We reviewed the space syntax model. As noted by Zhang et al. (2022, p. 9434). “[a] higher level of integration implies spatial clustering and better topological accessibility”. Some space syntax measures correlate well with accessibility, however accessibility is sufficiently distinct that it is not an appropriate comparator.

3. Some relevant references should be cited as follow:

• The influence of the spatial pattern of urban road networks on the quality of business environments: the case of Dalian City. Environment, Development and Sustainability (2022) 24:9429–9446. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-021-01832-z

• Differences in Accessibility of Public Health Facilities in Hierarchical Municipalities and the Spatial Pattern Characteristics of Their Services in Doumen District, China. Land 2021, 10, 1249. https://doi.org/10.3390/land10111249.

• Transportation Accessibility Evaluation of Educational Institutions Conducting Field Environmental Education Activities in Ecological Protection Areas: A Case Study of Zhuhai City. Sustainability 2021, 13, 9392. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13169392

Thank you for these references, which we have added to the bibliography in the paper.

We trust that you will find that these revisions satisfy all the comments communicated. We are grateful for your insightful and constructive feedback, and appreciate that it helped to improve the paper.

Attachment

Submitted filename: 2022.09.22 - Response letter to reviewers.pdf

Decision Letter 1

Jun Yang

17 Nov 2022

Introducing spatial availability, a singly-constrained measure of competitive accessibility

PONE-D-22-24454R1

Dear Dr. Soukhov,

We’re pleased to inform you that your manuscript has been judged scientifically suitable for publication and will be formally accepted for publication once it meets all outstanding technical requirements.

Within one week, you’ll receive an e-mail detailing the required amendments. When these have been addressed, you’ll receive a formal acceptance letter and your manuscript will be scheduled for publication.

An invoice for payment will follow shortly after the formal acceptance. To ensure an efficient process, please log into Editorial Manager at http://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/, click the 'Update My Information' link at the top of the page, and double check that your user information is up-to-date. If you have any billing related questions, please contact our Author Billing department directly at authorbilling@plos.org.

If your institution or institutions have a press office, please notify them about your upcoming paper to help maximize its impact. If they’ll be preparing press materials, please inform our press team as soon as possible -- no later than 48 hours after receiving the formal acceptance. Your manuscript will remain under strict press embargo until 2 pm Eastern Time on the date of publication. For more information, please contact onepress@plos.org.

Kind regards,

Jun Yang

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Additional Editor Comments (optional):

Accept

Reviewers' comments:

Reviewer's Responses to Questions

Comments to the Author

1. If the authors have adequately addressed your comments raised in a previous round of review and you feel that this manuscript is now acceptable for publication, you may indicate that here to bypass the “Comments to the Author” section, enter your conflict of interest statement in the “Confidential to Editor” section, and submit your "Accept" recommendation.

Reviewer #1: (No Response)

Reviewer #2: All comments have been addressed

**********

2. Is the manuscript technically sound, and do the data support the conclusions?

The manuscript must describe a technically sound piece of scientific research with data that supports the conclusions. Experiments must have been conducted rigorously, with appropriate controls, replication, and sample sizes. The conclusions must be drawn appropriately based on the data presented.

Reviewer #1: (No Response)

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

3. Has the statistical analysis been performed appropriately and rigorously?

Reviewer #1: (No Response)

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

4. Have the authors made all data underlying the findings in their manuscript fully available?

The PLOS Data policy requires authors to make all data underlying the findings described in their manuscript fully available without restriction, with rare exception (please refer to the Data Availability Statement in the manuscript PDF file). The data should be provided as part of the manuscript or its supporting information, or deposited to a public repository. For example, in addition to summary statistics, the data points behind means, medians and variance measures should be available. If there are restrictions on publicly sharing data—e.g. participant privacy or use of data from a third party—those must be specified.

Reviewer #1: (No Response)

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

5. Is the manuscript presented in an intelligible fashion and written in standard English?

PLOS ONE does not copyedit accepted manuscripts, so the language in submitted articles must be clear, correct, and unambiguous. Any typographical or grammatical errors should be corrected at revision, so please note any specific errors here.

Reviewer #1: (No Response)

Reviewer #2: Yes

**********

6. Review Comments to the Author

Please use the space provided to explain your answers to the questions above. You may also include additional comments for the author, including concerns about dual publication, research ethics, or publication ethics. (Please upload your review as an attachment if it exceeds 20,000 characters)

Reviewer #1: The authors have adequately addressed comments raised in a previous round of review and I feel that this manuscript is now acceptable for publication

Reviewer #2: All comments have been addressed. The authors have revised relevant problems. This paper could be accepted.

**********

7. PLOS authors have the option to publish the peer review history of their article (what does this mean?). If published, this will include your full peer review and any attached files.

If you choose “no”, your identity will remain anonymous but your review may still be made public.

Do you want your identity to be public for this peer review? For information about this choice, including consent withdrawal, please see our Privacy Policy.

Reviewer #1: No

Reviewer #2: No

**********

Acceptance letter

Jun Yang

11 Jan 2023

PONE-D-22-24454R1

Introducing spatial availability, a singly-constrained measure of competitive accessibility

Dear Dr. Soukhov:

I'm pleased to inform you that your manuscript has been deemed suitable for publication in PLOS ONE. Congratulations! Your manuscript is now with our production department.

If your institution or institutions have a press office, please let them know about your upcoming paper now to help maximize its impact. If they'll be preparing press materials, please inform our press team within the next 48 hours. Your manuscript will remain under strict press embargo until 2 pm Eastern Time on the date of publication. For more information please contact onepress@plos.org.

If we can help with anything else, please email us at plosone@plos.org.

Thank you for submitting your work to PLOS ONE and supporting open access.

Kind regards,

PLOS ONE Editorial Office Staff

on behalf of

Dr. Jun Yang

Academic Editor

PLOS ONE

Associated Data

    This section collects any data citations, data availability statements, or supplementary materials included in this article.

    Supplementary Materials

    S1 Appendix

    (PDF)

    Attachment

    Submitted filename: 2022.09.22 - Response letter to reviewers.pdf

    Data Availability Statement

    Data relevant to this study are available from Github at DOI:10.5281/zenodo.6450308 (https://soukhova.github.io/TTS2016R/) and the code at https://github.com/soukhova/Spatial-Availability-Measure.


    Articles from PLOS ONE are provided here courtesy of PLOS

    RESOURCES